Saturday, January 19, 2013

Is Finance Too Big?

mesothelioma survival rates australia,mesothelioma survival rates uk,mesothelioma survival rates after surgery,mesothelioma survival rates wiki,mesothelioma mortality rates,mesothelioma survival rate stage 1,mesothelioma survival rate by stage,mesothelioma survival rate stage 2,mesothelioma survival rate without treatment,mesothelioma survival rate 2015,peritoneal mesothelioma survival rates,mesothelioma survival rates in usa introduction,abdominal mesothelioma survival rates,mesothelioma prognosis survival,stage 4 mesothelioma survival rates,survival rates mesothelioma cancer,survival rates for mesothelioma,survival rates for malignant mesothelioma,what is mesothelioma survival rates,survival rates of mesothelioma,mesothelioma surgery survival rates,insurance quotes,insurance companies,insurance near me,insurance broker,insurance definition,insurance auto auction,insurance premium,insurance adjuster,insurance marketplace,insurance deductible,insurance in spanish,insurance agent salary,insurance journal,insurance jobs,insurance agent,insuranceclaimcheck,insurance companies near me,insurance license,insurance car,insurance agency,insurance agents near me,insurance auto,insurance adjuster jobs,insurance agency near me,insurance agent jobs,insurance actuary,insurance attorney,insurance agent job description,insurance adjuster license,insurance associates,insurance adjuster salary,insurance agent license,insurance agency for sale,insurance appraiser,insurance binder,insurance broker near me,insurance broker salary,insurance breast pump,insurance by the mile,insurance bond,insurance broker license,insurance bee,insurance broker definition,insurance beneficiary,insurance blackjack,insurance broker vs agent,insurance business,insurance bad faith,insurance brokerage firms,insurance blockchain,insurance brokers of mn,insurance board,insurance claim,insurance commissioner,insurance card,insurance claim check,insurance calculator,insurance can help you,insurance company ratings,insurance carrier,insurance coverage,insurance commercials,insurance claims adjuster,insurance comparison,insurance companies in florida,insurance commission,insurance cost,insurance careers,insurance declaration page,insurance depot,insurance doctor,insurance designations,insurance direct,insurance declaration,insurance department,insurance discounts,insurance defense,insurance def,insurance dental,insurance dictionary,insurance defense attorney,insurance degree,insurance design administrators,insurance denial codes,insurance donut hole,insurance estimator,insurance exchange,insurance express,insurance endorsement,insurance exam,insurance etf,insurance enrollment,insurance exchange of america,insurance education,insurance eob,insurance exemption,insurance effective date,insurance estimate car,insurance education association,insurance examiner,insurance estimator jobs,insurance epo,insurance expense asset or liability,insurance exposure,insurance for dogs,insurance for kids,insurance for cars,insurance for veterans,insurance fraud investigator,insurance forums,insurance for college students,insurance for students,insurance for pregnant women,insurance for small business,insurance for rental cars,insurance form for taxes,insurance for less,insurance for braces,insurance for pets,insurance for dummies,insurance for rental property,insurance for teens,insurance for uber drivers,insurance geico,insurance group number,insurance general,insurance group,insurance giant,insurance glossary,insurance group number on card,insurance guy,insurance gov,insurance gap,insurance gif,insurance ga,insurance general agent,insurance guarantee association,insurance gap between jobs,insurance group of america,insurance girl,insurance game,insurance guaranty fund,insurance health,insurance house,insurance handbook for the medical office,insurance hub,insurance hmo,insurance headhunters,insurance history,insurance holder,insurance health companies,insurance humor,insurance hit and run,insurance hsa,insurance hours,insurance helper,insurance hra,insurance hotline,insurance huntsville al,insurance humana,insurance helpline,insurance insider,insurance institute for highway safety,insurance industry,insurance investigator,insurance institute,insurance information institute,insurance institute of america,insurance is a financial service that allows a,insurance icon,insurance inspector,insurance in blackjack,insurance investigator jobs,insurance industry trends,insurance id number,insurance industry news,insurance internships,insurance images,insurance intermediaries inc,insurance jobs near me,insurance jokes,insurance jobs from home,insurance jobs atlanta,insurance jobs salary,insurance jobs for nurses,insurance jobs houston,insurance jingles,insurance jobs tampa,insurance job titles,insurance jobs san diego,insurance jobs charlotte nc,insurance jobs denver,insurance jobs richmond va,insurance jobs san antonio,insurance jobs in ct,insurance jobs in nj,insurance king,insurance king commercial,insurance key terms,insurance kaiser,insurance king rockford il,insurance king reviews,insurance knowledge,insurance ky,insurance killeen tx,insurance kansas city,insurance king ohio,insurance kentucky,insurance kennewick wa,insurance keywords,insurance keeps going up,insurance kalamazoo,insurance king hours,insurance klamath falls,insurance kannapolis nc,insurance kpis,insurance lawyer,insurance leads,insurance lapse,insurance logos,insurance land,insurance law,insurance license ca,insurance linked securities,insurance license classes,insurance license texas,insurance life event,insurance license ga,insurance license exam,insurance license lookup ca,insurance license nc,insurance loss ratio,insurance lounge,insurance license search,insurance mandate,insurance meaning,insurance meme,insurance management services,insurance medical,insurance marketing,insurance mga,insurance mandate 2018,insurance management group,insurance man,insurance marketing ideas,insurance manager salary,insurance mayhem,insurance magazines,insurance mart,insurance manager,insurance michigan,insurance m,insurance news,insurance navy,insurance number,insurance noodle,insurance nation,insurance news net,insurance nurse jobs,insurance network,insurance now,insurance names,insurance nexus,insurance national producer number,insurance nurse,insurance nationwide,insurance naic number,insurance navigator,insurance news articles,insurance nerds,insurance online,insurance one,insurance office of america,insurance on the spot,insurance open enrollment,insurance options,insurance offers consumers,insurance online quote,insurance one agency,insurance on the go,insurance offices near me,insurance overload,insurance on a new car,insurance out of pocket,insurance on a leased car,insurance on rental car,insurance open today,insurance on a camaro,insurance on iphone,insurance policy,insurance policy number,insurance plans,insurance panda,insurance penalty,insurance providers,insurance policy definition,insurance places near me,insurance penalty 2017,insurance producer,insurance progressive,insurance plus,insurance places,insurance prices,insurance proceeds taxable,insurance penalty 2018,insurance ppo,insurance payor,insurance quote online,insurance quotes car,insurance quotes texas,insurance quote geico,insurance qualifying event,insurance questions,insurance quotes ga,insurance quote progressive,insurance quotes florida,insurance quotes health,insurance quotes nj,insurance quote state farm,insurance quotes ny,insurance quotes pa,insurance quizlet,insurance quote comparison,insurance quotes az,insurance quotes michigan,insurance rates,insurance rider,insurance risk,insurance reimbursement,insurance recruiters,insurance reviews,insurance rates by state,insurance risk manager,insurance retention,insurance rate calculator,insurance risk services,insurance rates by car,insurance regulation,insurance rebating,insurance reserves,insurance resume,insurance rental car,insurance rn jobs,insurance referral,insurance sales,insurance services,insurance service center,insurance services office,insurance solutions,insurance sales jobs,insurance sales agent,insurance specialist,insurance score,insurance subscriber,insurance schools,insurance sales salary,insurance stocks,insurance scams,insurance state farm,insurance settlement,insurance subscriber number,insurance synonyms,insurance slogans,insurance terms,insurance types,insurance tax form,insurance to go,insurance tpa,insurance test,insurance types word search,insurance training,insurance technology,insurance the general,insurance that covers ivf,insurance trust,insurance tax penalty 2018,insurance tax credit,insurance thought leadership,insurance total loss,insurance that covers braces,insurance tax penalty 2017,insurance tax,insurance underwriter,insurance underwriter salary,insurance underwriter jobs,insurance unlimited,insurance umbrella,insurance underwriting process,insurance usaa,insurance umbrella policy,insurance underwriter definition,insurance usps,insurance until 26,insurance uber,insurance university,insurance utah,insurance umr,insurance united,insurance usps cost,insurance underwriter resume,insurance underwriter training,insurance verification,insurance verification form,insurance verification jobs,insurance value,insurance verification specialist,insurance vocabulary,insurance verifier,insurance verizon,insurance vin check,insurance value chain,insurance violation,insurance value of my car,insurance verifier salary,insurance vs assurance,insurance verification salary,insurance verification specialist resume,insurance verification training,insurance veterans,insurance verification specialist job description,insurance verification letter,assurance wireless,insurance world,insurance waiver,insurance work from home jobs,insurance warehouse,insurance website builder,insurance wiki,insurance west,insurance wholesaler,insurance when buying a new car,insurance waiting period,insurance with the general,insurance work from home,insurance wichita ks,insurance write off,insurance words,assurance wireless customer service,insurance with no car,insurance x dates,insurance xchange,insurance xpress,insurance xenia ohio,insurance x dates leads,insurance x c u,insurance co,insurance xactimate,insurance xchange bustleton ave,insurance xfinity mobile,insurance xml standards,insurance x date definition,insurance check,insurance xol,insurance xl catlin,insurance xl,insurance xl group,insurance yuma az,insurance yakima,insurance york pa,insurance yuba city,insurance you can buy online,insurance you need,insurance youtube,insurance yellow book,insurance yelp,insurance yukon ok,insurance you almost had it,insurance yearly cost,insurance yonkers ny,insurance year,insurance yugioh,insurance yuba city ca,insurance youngstown ohio,insurance yanceyville nc,insurance you should have,insurance yuma,insurance zebra,insurance zone,insurance zone destin,insurance zombie apocalypse,insurance zone destin fl,insurance zurich,insurance zip code rating,insurance zephyrhills fl,insurance zipcar,insurance zebra review,insurance zeeland mi,insurance zanesville ohio,insurance zander,insurance zebulon nc,insurance zip code,insurance zenni optical,insurance zachary la,insurance zebulon ga,insurance zebra crunchbase,insurance quotes online,insurance quotes geico,insurance quotes comparison,insurance quotes colorado,insurance quotes california,insurance quotes sc,insurance quotes indiana,insurance quotes ky,insurance quotes allstate home design,house plans,house designs,home plans,house design,living room design,home interior design,small house plans,bedroom design,home interior,house interior design,house floor plans,house decoration,building plans,small house design,interior design websites,floor plans,home design plans,interior design for living room,home floor plans,new home designs,room design,best home design,small home design,modern house design,house interior,new house design,small home plans,cottage house plans,house blueprints,modern house plans,best interior design,new home plans,custom home plans,modern home design,house building plans,house plan design,best house designs,bedroom interior design,craftsman house plans,home building plans,ranch house plans,custom house plans,architecture design for home,simple house plans,design your own house,bedroom interior,design your home,best house plans,country house plans,small house floor plans,blueprint homes,house plans and more,one story house plans,custom home designs,design my home,bungalow house plans,house designers,ranch style house plans,bedroom designer,dream house plans,exterior home design,modern home plans,contemporary house designs,home decor,latest home design,interior home decoration,new house plans,house plans and designs,contemporary house plans,design for house,best interior design websites,narrow lot house plans,design my own house,interior design,room interior design,single story house plans,home dizayn,design my house,design your house,beach house plans,ranch home plans,new home floor plans,house construction plan,dream home plans,home and design,modern interior design,house interior decoration,designer houses,craftsman style house plans,beautiful house plans,craftsman home plans,custom home floor plans,designer house,2 story house plans,home construction plans,custom floor plans,desing home,home design websites,new interior design,interior design sites,residential building plans,architecture design house,simple house design,french country house plans,interior home,dream home design,unique house plans,contemporary home design,residential house plans,exterior house design,design your own house plans,ranch floor plans,contemporary interior design,mediterranean house plans,shop interior design,home decoration design,home building design,homeinteriors,build your own house plans,house plans with porches,in home design,interior decoration,best home interior design,design your dream house,home plans and more,at home design,architectural design house plans,new home interior design,architectural house plans,contemporary home plans,house design and floor plan,my house plans,house layout plans,home architecture,colonial house plans,house design inside,house models and plans,two storey house plans,open floor house plans,small space interior design,dizain home,country style house plans,european house plans,house design websites,indian interior design,home layout planner,home dezine,open plan house,2 storey house plans,new house floor plans,building design,townhouse designs and floor plans,house plan drawing,h0me design,home designer architectural,modern floor plans,large house plans,home inside design,in house design,latest home interior design,building design plan,living room decor ideas,architectural floor plans,architectural home plans,new house interior design,architecture and design houses,single level house plans,hd home design,home floor plan designer,home plans and designs,country house design,traditional house plans,house layout,home design home design,model house plan,virtual interior design,interior design books,house building design,dream home floor plans,design interior,home decor ideas,house inner design,home by design,home house design,home design software,cottage home plans,house floor plan design,interior design magazine,italian interior design,house decorating ideas,floor plan designer,home house plans,home get dizain,house design software,best home plans,home internal design,best home interior design websites,new home blueprints,internal house design,interior design images,home design sites,home interior ideas,building plans and designs,my house design,houses and plans,modern house floor plans,home interior design ideas,classic interior design,unique home plans,beach house designs,home inner design,interior design software,home interiors catalog,custom home blueprints,internal decoration of house,interior design online,interior decorating ideas,modern home interior design,blueprint house plans,residential blueprints,interior design ideas,living room design ideas,new style home design,new house plans and prices,home design images,home get design,interior design ideas for living room,3d home design software,house layout design,home design furniture,new construction house plans,custom house designs,house floor plans and prices,house plans online,villa designs and floor plans,home designs and interiors,bedroom design ideas,house plan interior design,villa plans and designs,residential home plans,residential design,home indoor design,interior home plans,new build house designs,find house plans,modern decor ideas,home interior design websites,big house plans,car interior design,interior designer,home design online,beautiful home interior designs,dream house floor plans,home design interior design,interior design photos,unusual house plans,country home plans,residential floor plans,free home design software,interior design ideas bedroom,simple house floor plan,unique house designs,decoration ideas,new home building plans,interior design styles,residential house design,new model house interior design,home design app,free house plans,free home plans,residential house design plans,project house,luxury house design,house model,i design homes,house building plans and prices,architectural design home plans,new dizain home,house design online,great house plans,designer in the house,house indoor design,narrow house plans,house plans floor plans,house and home plans,office interior design ideas,home design 3d,build your own home plans,new home layouts,find house blueprints,homes and interiors,beautiful house interior design,house floor design,country home designs,room design ideas,dizajn home,house get dizain,home design home,house plans by design,townhouse plans,new design home plans,interior design games,interior ideas,my home plan,house interior design ideas,free interior design software,floor plans for building a house,luxury house floor plans,how to design a house,blueprint home plans,a house design,new house blueprints,new home construction plans,home design design,new house plan design,home design magazines,home design ideas,dream house blueprints,house design house design,new latest home design,modern contemporary interior design,best house interior designs,latest house interior designs,3d interior design,home plans with photos,all home design,house and design,house blueprint maker,house room design,home interiors,home blueprint designer,3d house plans,hom design,house blueprint designer,interior colour design,home builders floor plans,luxury home design,3d house design,new home floor plans and prices,house projects plans,home planners inc house plans,design your own home online,house to home designs,plan your home design,house design sites,modern interior design ideas,latest house designs,new build designs,home design house plans,h0use plans,from house design,home interior design plans,custom home design plans,home floor design,build your own house floor plans,where to find house plans,design plan,home designs and floor plans,the best home design,your home design,indoor house design,architectural design floor plans,what is interior design,best home interiors,villa design plan,where to get house plans,interior decorating styles,condo interior design,residential building design plans,interior design pictures,family home plans,contemporary interior designers,interior design portfolio,a home design,house design ideas,home design inside style,design from home,house pictures designs,build it house plans,internal home decoration,homes models and plans,cheap interior design,architectural design plans,interior house plans,house plan maker,interior design help,new house room design,house layout maker,best dizain home,new build floor plans,hd house design,house architecture,house dsgn,house building blueprints,build your home,apartment interior design,in design homes,home out design,latest building designs and plans,residential house plans and designs,home design and decor,home decoration tips,new build house plans,interior design tips,interior design and decoration,in house designer,architectural design,build your house,home building blueprints,house in design,get design house,custom house blueprints,interior design trends,interior design blogs,home ideas,interior design show,design your own home plans,house creator,in home designer,build own house plans,french interior design,designers homes,house of interior design,house room interior design,architectural plans,house designer builder,architecture design house interior,free interior design,home design photo,house construction plans and designs,interior design inspiration,build house plans design,virtual home design,home for design,housing blueprints floor plans,home interior design photos,home design free,home room design,house and home design,latest model home design,blueprints for my home,interior design stores,design your house plans,famous interior designers,inhouse plans,inside house designs plans,the home designers,history of interior design,cheap hotels,booking hotel,hotel deals,booking hotels,last minute hotel deals,hotel room,hotel search,hotel finder,hotel websites,discount hotels,last minute hotels,hotel booking sites,cheap hotel rooms,cheap hotel deals,book hotels,hotels near me,best hotel deals,hotel prices,hotel reservations,online hotel booking,cheap accommodation,cheap rooms,hotel sites,best hotel prices,hotel rates,discount hotel sites,cheap hotel rooms near me,hotel booking websites,find cheap hotels,hotel search engines,cheap hotel booking,motel,cheap hotel sites,best hotel booking site,nearby hotels,hotels near,cheap hotel prices,hotel comparison,budget hotel,cheap motels,hotel chains,best hotels,best hotel rates,hotel search sites,local hotels,hotel room booking,discount hotel rooms,luxury hotels,hotel s,boutique hotel,hotel booking offers,best hotel website,hotels in,hotel online,low cost hotels,hotel last minute,the hotel,hotel packages,book accommodation,cheap hotel websites,hotel accommodation,a hotel,low price hotels,cheap hotel reservations,5 star hotel,discount hotel rates,lowest hotel rates,cheap hotel rates,hotel reservation sites,hotel rentals,hotel breakers,hotel a,cheap hotel booking sites,cheap hotels in,suite,hotels rooms,hotel offers,hotel bargains,hotel suites,cheap hotel suites,best hotel finder,hotel rate,hotel deal sites,cheap last minute hotels,find hotel deals,best hotel sites,discount hotel websites,cheap hotel search,airport hotel,late hotel deals,discount hotel deals,find hotel rooms,hotel room prices,hotel room deals,suite hotels,best cheap hotels,motel discounts,cheap hotel stays,best hotel search,cheap hotel offers,accommodation sites,great hotel deals,hotel deals websites,hotel finder websites,travel hotel,hotel finder sites,hotel resort,affordable hotels,cheap hotel rentals,hotel booking deals,hotel room booking sites,top hotel,last minute hotel booking,hotel booking discount,discount hotel prices,beach hotel,discount rooms,looking for hotels,find hotels near address,last minute hotel rooms,hotel suite,cheap cheap hotels,find me a hotel,very cheap hotels,where to book cheap hotels,cheap hotel discounts,five star hotel,hotel room finder,online hotel reservation,good deals on hotels,discount hotel reservations,where to find cheap hotels,hotel deals near me,book cheap hotels online,where to book hotels,inexpensive hotels,bargain hotel deals,bookit hotels,hotel price finder,cheap hotel accommodation,best hotel booking,best hotel rooms,hotel room rates,book cheap hotel rooms,business hotel,hotel inn,best site to find hotels,hotel at,cheap lodges,websites to book hotels,hotel prices near me,hotels and resorts,hotel room search,cheap hotel packages,find cheap hotel rooms,cheapest site to book hotels,discount accommodation,com hotel,best hotel discount sites,best deals on hotel rooms,cheap hotel breaks,hotel room reservation,find me a hotel room,reserve hotel,good cheap hotels,low cost hotel rooms,best price hotel rooms,hotels downtown,cheap hotels i,online hotel deals,discount hotel booking sites,late hotels,best hotel discounts,cheap luxury hotels,cheap hotel booking website,hotels on,hotel reservation websites,room deal,the cheapest hotel,hotel accommodation deals,hotels cheap hotels,cheap accommodation deals,cheapest place to book hotels,book a room near me,hotel search websites,hotel hotel,best hotel rates online,looking for cheap hotels,4 star hotel,cheap hotels at,find cheap hotel deals,hotel room websites,hotel price search,get cheap hotel rates,gets hotel,get cheap hotels,discount lodging,3 star hotel,websites to find cheap hotels,get hotel deals,places to book hotels,economy hotel,cheapest website to book hotels,hotel room sites,hot deals hotels,search hotel deals,book hotel reservations,find cheap hotel rates,find me a cheap hotel,cheap hotels on,area hotel,best site for hotel deals,best hotel price finder,book cheap rooms,low price hotel rooms,hotels around,best offers on hotel booking,booking hotels in,a cheap hotel,to book a hotel,bargain hotel rooms,cheap hotels motels,cheapest hotel rates online,late hotel rooms,where can i find cheap hotels,find best hotel rates,cheap hotel chains,where to find cheap hotel deals,inexpensive hotel rooms,hotel bargain sites,low price hotel booking,best website to find hotels,hotel offers near me,find best hotel deals,best deal in hotel booking,hotel suite deals,lowest hotel deals,hotel motel,good hotel prices,cheap hotels online,find lodging,great hotel rates,where to get cheap hotels,looking for hotel deals,book hotel now,hotel rate finder,best website to find cheap hotels,hotel savings sites,web booking hotel,book cheap accommodation,search all hotels,discount hotel suites,hotel hotel hotel,cheap hotels and motels,where to book hotel,hotel booking in,discount luxury hotels,websites to book cheap hotels,find cheap motels,reservation hotel,cheap room rates,sites to find cheap hotels,great hotel prices,best site for cheap hotels,compare hotel prices,cheap accommodation sites,find discount hotels,get cheap hotel rooms,sites to book cheap hotels,hotel booking cheapest rates,discount hotel search,best place to book hotels,hotel for,book hotel with,i need a hotel room,cheap lodge deals,hotels uk,find available hotel rooms,find cheap rooms,find a hotel room near me,hotels in price,hotel low cost,cheap hotel room rates,family hotel,best price for hotel booking,hotel rate search,the hotel book,find cheap accommodation,hotel france,extended stay hotels,where to find hotels,find hotel prices,book a room hotel,cheap discount hotel rooms,best cheap hotel finder,hotel directory,hotell,find hotels online,hotel de charme,hotel suite finder,budget hotel booking,special hotel rates,cheap hotel deals and discounts,affordable hotel rooms,get a hotel room,cheap hotel specials,book hotel accommodation,hotel motel discounts,accommodation low priced,find cheap hotel prices,pet friendly hotels,book in hotels,cheap hotels a,romantic hotels,find cheap hotels online,cheap and hotel,aparthotel,hotel club,compare hotel rates,hotels near me booking,cheap hotel reservations online,cheap and best hotel,hotel reservation service,awesome hotel,hotel room booking website,cheap hotel room websites,low price hotels near me,hotel specials,best site to look for hotels,all suites hotel,cheap motels nearby,hotel reviews,best hotel room rates,hotel savings websites,find hotel availability,hotel saving sites,how to find cheap hotels,website of hotel,four star hotel,best site to book cheap hotels,a hotel booking,cheap reservations,rooms hotel,cheap hotel room sites,hotel rooms online,best site to find hotel deals,hotel availability finder,cheapest hotel deals online,discount accommodation sites,to book a hotel room,hotel travel,find the hotel,great hotel deals near me,bellagio hotel,address hotel,accommodation booking websites,best website to book cheap hotels,cheap hotel deals near me,for hotel reservations,discount hotel stays,disneyland hotel,cheapest hotel prices online,luxor hotel,hotel rooms in,places to stay,hotels and prices,hotel suite search,booking in a hotel,reasonable hotel rooms,metatrader 4,forex trading,forex valuta,forex demo,forex pro,trader forex,forex robot,fx forex,forex signals,forex eur usd,bonus forex,forex euro,expert advisor,forex trading software,forex usd,forex spread,forex strategie,valuta forex,valuta trading,forex dollar,forex trading for dummies,forex trading in india,options trading,forex for dummies,trading on line,forex indonesia,trading online,currency trading for dummies,trading platforms,forex handel,online share trading,day trading software,forex trading training,forex trading course,fx trading,forex malaysia,online stock trading,share trading,trading signals,trading software,forex trading platforms,canadian forex,forex bonus,top forex,learn forex trading,forex demo account,free forex signals,stock market trading,best forex signals,stock trading,best forex trading platform,best forex broker,best online trading stocks,stock trading software,forex trading tutorial,how to trade forex,fx broker,online trading,online trading account,forex trading tips,commodity trading,forex trading books,forex training,forex trading for beginners,daytrading,forex trading strategies,belajar forex,ea forex,day trading,online broker,online trading platforms,automated trading,cfd trading,forex trading signals,currency trading,trading courses,i forex,forex broker,forex uk,forex analysis,forex account,what is forex trading,trading account,broker forex,foreign exchange trading,metatrader,forex ea,intraday trading,top forex brokers,forex investing,forex for beginners,online forex trading,meta trader 4,day trade,forex indicators,trading,day trading stocks,forex trading basics,currency options trading,trading strategies,forex strategies,futures trading,forex trading demo,forex trading system,forex forecast,metatrader 5,forex simulator,no deposit bonus forex,forex trading hours,gold trader,trading system,live forex charts,fx trader,forex market,day trader,forex kontor,forex trading broker,paper trading,forex exchange,how to trade currency,trade market,managed forex accounts,forex currency,day trading strategies,instaforex,forex strategy,simulated forex trading,forex australia,forex reviews,forex trading reviews,forex books,learn forex,forex technical analysis,forex charts,best forex robot,forex online,best online trading,forex tips,forex options,free forex charts,ukforex,forum forex,online forex,forex capital,scalping forex,forexlive,forex forum,dailyfx,stock trading strategies,forex trading australia,forex india,forex software,best forex strategy,forex pdf,forex platform,foreign currency trading,fx options,automated trading system,cfd,forex news,finanzas forex,forex currency exchange,forex education,spread trading,forex trading education,lite forex,currency market,forex club,forex rate,best forex,fibonacci trading,fx market,forex broker reviews,gold forex,global forex,foreign currency,forex company,forex tutorial,forex exchange rate,online currency trading,fx charts,money trade,forex calculator,iforex,technical analysis,forex blog,oanda forex,swing trading,what is forex,e forex,fx signals,foreign currency exchange,forex day trading,trading markets,forex bank,forex signal provider,forex contest,exchange rate,forex news live,forex market hours,fxcm,forex tester,easy forex,forex trend,option trading software,foreign exchange market,forex money,forex trading uk,forex system,foreign currency exchange rates,best forex indicator,trend trading,online trading software,forexworld,pip forex,how to do forex trading,foreign exchange,swiss forex,fibonacci forex,forex capital markets,forex trading forex rates forex market,forex brokers list,forex trading account,online commodity trading,forex course,forex wiki,fx trading platforms,forex basics,currency chart,trader,live forex rates,فركس,forex signal service,currency exchange rate,forex school,what is leverage in forex,alpari,forex money exchange,forex quotes,forex predictions,foreign exchange broker,fx currency,currency broker,forex currency rates,forex currency trading,fx street,automated forex trading,forex converter,forex business,forex calendar,forex currency converter,currency rate,ecn forex,best forex platform,metastock,foreign exchange calculator,forex affiliate,forex expert advisor,mt4 forex,forex cargo,master forex,fx exchange,4x trading,forex exchange market,currency trading tips,guide for forex trading,forex directory,forex historical data,hedging forex,money forex,fx trading strategies,forex market news,forex mobile,forex game,forex trading forum,forex trading robot,real time forex,forest trading,internet trading,gft forex,forex broker comparison,accurate forex signals,forex market analysis,forex scam,free forex trading,forex trading times,forex cfd,global forex trading,forex futures,forex metatrader,fx news,forex trading charts,forex trading simulator,cms forex,forex trading news,free forex,live forex trading,forex video,forex practice account,traders,what is forex market,forex data,fx pro,fx rates,currency trading basics,forex bot,forex guide,forex training course,best forex trading system,forex trading companies,action forex,forex jobs,what is fx trading,forex peace army,forex website,forex metal,what is currency trading,bforex trading,free forex robot,forex alerts,online foreign exchange,forex on line,management accounting,go forex,best forex trading software,fx online,x forex,about forex trading,forex trading wiki,learn to day trade,free forex trading signals,expert advisors,forex profit,currencies,change money forex,forex help,best forex traders,forex trader pro,forex arbitrage,forex advisor,day trading online,forex factory,forex trading scams,forex ebook,about forex,forex trading website,forex mentor,currency trading strategies,capital forex,managed forex,forex download,automated forex trading software,jutawan forex,forex charting software,forex tools,fx account,forex seminar,currency exchange,learn forex trading online,free forex training,forex market trading,forex auto trader,forexmarket,forex trading plan,forex göteborg,how to forex,forex broker rating,forex secrets,forex exchange trading,forex services,real forex,earnforex,forex stock,swing trading forex,forex trading school,forex history,stock market trading software,forex trading practice,free forex trading course,stock trading system,commodity futures trading,forex brokerage,forex chat,treding forex,forex dealers,easy forex trading,ava forex,forex marketing,forex trading sites,currency trading platforms,i forex trading,forex scalping system,metatrader brokers,currency calculator,forex forex,spot forex,best forex software,what is margin in forex,forex sites,forex trading tools,fapturbo,forex management,forex trading indicators,forex tv,all about forex trading,forex trading techniques,day trading courses,forex capital market,forex tsd,currency futures trading,forex trading game,online forex trading platforms,forex megadroid,forex trading contest,forex trading room,forex pairs,forex trading secrets,forex foreign exchange,currency,forex trading analysis,online forex brokers,automatic forex trading,online forex trading course,best forex system,the forex,reuters forex,forex trading adalah,forex price,online forex trading account,forex expert,future,commodity,learn currency trading,forex signals software,forex information,currency market trading,bforex online trading,fx forex trading,automated forex trading system,cmc forex,forex bank valuta,online future trading,currency converter,futures trading software,acm forex,forex fund,forex options trading,currency trading software,online forex trading forex,forex program,online forex exchange,forex practice,managed forex trading,forex trading blog,online fx trading,forex trading seminar,fx trading signals,futures trading system,forex ab,forex trend trading,stock market day trading,international forex trading,system forex,fx trading software,4x market,forex bank logga in,automatic forex trading software,free forex trading software,make money forex trading,the forex market,forex advice,forex trading information,forex trading mentors,forex autopilot,forex made easy,currency trading account,make money with forex,what is forex trading all about,fortex trading,forex global,where to trade forex,what is forex exchange,fx currency trading,forex day trading strategies,online forex trading system,forex mini account,gci forex,currency exchange trading,forex killer,interbank fx,what is bforex,forex futures trading,whats forex,currency news trading,what's forex trading,introducing broker forex,fx trading system,currency trading courses,currency forex online trading,spot forex trading,forex t,forex norge,best forex training,day trading systems,all about forex,forex trading programs,mini forex,forex c,market maker forex,currency trading system,forex trading usa,forex easy,fx money exchange,mobile forex trading,forex trading club,currency trading brokers,microfx,forex kontakt,forex trading methods,autofx,forex currency broker,forex daytrading,que es forex trading,forex yard,forex recommendations,forex trading made easy,currency option trading,what's forex,fx money,in forex,4x forex,online foreign exchange trading,forex micro,trade and forex,when to trade forex,forex money changer,online forex training,forex trading signals software,how to trade in forex market,forex trading services,fibonacci forex trading,forex research,forex trading advice,foreign exchange currency trading,forex bank internetbank,förex,currency trading charts,forex in,what is iforex,forex trading alerts,forex bank ab,interbank forex,forex now,forex trading what is it,about forex market,ex forex,marketing fx,fx automated trading,forex day trading system,free forex trading systems,forex best,what is bforex trading,fx trader exchange rates,forex bank malmö,forex english,what is iforex and how does it work,crown forex,pro forex,forex trading today,forex trading station,forex trading forex,currency trading training,define forex trading,forex bank göteborg,currency trading site,foreign exchange market trading,forex bank kontakt,forex market today,forex trading money,fx dealer,forex bank norway,bank forex trading,day trading currency,tentang forex trading,what is forex trading online,forex bank kundtjänst,forex bank öppettider,forex bank login,forex commentary,on line trading forex,forex forex trading,forex automoney,mini forex trading,forex trading forex rates forex,international forex market,currency trading website,trader fx,forex exchange sweden,fortex bank,currency trading signals,how to trade in foreign exchange market,how does forex exchange work,what is foreign exchange trading,online forex market,forex currency market,forexd,forex currency trading system,4x currency trading,forex trading explained,www forec,how to trade foreign currency online,forex trading info,international currency trading
Is finance too big? Here's a draft essay on the subject. There is a pdf on my webpage, and updates, revisions and a final version will end up there.

This came about as a "response essay" to Robin Greenwood and David Scharfstein's "The growth of modern finance" for the Journal of Economic Perspectives. That's why Robin and David are the target of a lot of criticism. But they're really just standing in for a lot of opinion that finance is "too big," in part because they did such a good and evenhanded job of synthesizing that point of view. So, sorry for picking on you, Robin and David!

I'm sure the JEP will make me cut it down and tone it down, so this is the fun first draft.


Is Finance Too Big?

John H. Cochrane [1],[2]
January 7 2013

I. Introduction

The US spends $150 billion a year on advertising and marketing[3]. $150 billion, just to trick people into buying stuff they don’t need. What a waste. 

There are 2.2 people doing medical billing for every doctor that actually sees patients, costing $360 billion[4] -- 2.4% of GDP. Talk about “too big!”

Wholesale, retail trade and transportation cost 14.6% of GDP, while all manufacturing is only 11.5% of GDP. We spend more to move stuff around than to make it! 

A while ago, my wife asked me to look at light fixtures. Have you seen how many thousands of different kinds of light fixtures there are? The excess complexity is insane. Ten ought to be plenty.

It’s ridiculous how much people overpay for brand names when they can get the generic a lot cheaper. They must be pretty naive.

Business school finance professors are horribly overpaid. Ask an anthropologist!  We must really have snowballed university administrations to get paid nearly half a million bucks, and work a grand total of 10 weeks a year, all to teach students that there is no alpha to be made in the stock market.

Did you know that Kim Kardashian gets $600,000 just to show up at a nightclub in Vegas?  How silly is that?

It’s a lot of fun to pass judgment on “social benefits,” “size,” “complexity” of industry, and “excessive compensation” of people who get paid more than we do, isn’t it? But it isn’t really that productive either.

As economists we have a structure for thinking about these questions.

We start with the first welfare theorem: loosely, supply, demand and competition lead to socially beneficial arrangements.  Yet the world around often doesn’t obviously conform to simple supply and demand arguments. See above. Then, we embark on a three-pronged investigation:  First, maybe there is something about the situation we don’t understand. Durable institutions and arrangements, despite competition and lack of government interference, sometimes take us years to understand. Second, maybe there is a “market failure,” an externality, public good, natural monopoly, asymmetric information, or missing market, that explains our puzzle.    Third, we often discover a “government failure,” that the puzzling aspect of our world is an unintended consequence of law or regulation. The regulators got captured, the market innovated around a regulation, or legal restrictions stop supply and demand from working.

Once we understand a puzzle, we are in a position to begin to diagnose a divergence between reality and socially desirable outcomes, and we can start to think of how to improve the outcome. But, though “some” may the world puzzling, or “many” might “voice concerns,” we don’t pronounce until we understand how one of these mechanisms describes the situation. Quantitatively: Cocktail-party externalities need not apply.

“I don’t understand it” doesn’t mean “it’s bad.” And since that attitude pervades regulation in general and financial regulation in particular, we do the world a disservice if we echo it.

I belabor this point, because I do not offer a competing black box. I don’t claim to estimate the socially-optimal “size of finance” at 8.267% of GDP, so there. Though apparently rhetorically effective, this is simply not how we do economics. After all, if a bunch of academics could sit around our offices and decide which industries were “too big,” which ones were “too small,” and close our papers with “policy recommendations” to remedy the matter, central planning would have worked.  A little Hayekian modesty suggests we focus on documenting the distortions, not pronouncing on optimal industry sizes.  Documenting distortions has also been, historically, far more productive than pronouncing on the optimal size of industries, optimal compensation of executives, “global imbalances,” “savings gluts,” “excessive consumption,” or other outcomes.

Furthermore, when we think about the social costs and benefits of finance, at this point in our history, it seems a bit strange to be arguing whether 5% or 8% of GDP is the right “size” of finance.  Looking back, I think that we would all happily accept 3% extra GDP in return for a financial system that is not prone to runs and crises. We are accepting a big increase in resources devoted to financial regulation and compliance, and a potentially larger reduction in the efficiency, innovation, and competitiveness of financial institutions and markets, in an attempt (misguided or not) to avoid runs and crises. And the run-prone nature of our financial system, together with consequently massive regulation and government guarantees, look like more fertile fishing ground for market and government failures than does mere size. Looking forward, insulating the financial system from sovereign default seems like a much more pressing issue than thinking of regulations to increase or reduce its “size.” 

Still, the size of finance represents a contentious issue, so let us think about it.

The financial services industry has grown a lot, reaching 8% of GDP. Greenwood and Scharfstein (2012) usefully focus the discussion by identifying the two areas of most significant revenue growth: asset management and fees associated with the expansion and refinancing of household debt.

The asset management story is straightforward:
“Individuals and institutions shifted an increasing share of their assets to investment management firms – first to mutual funds and institutional asset management firms (which mainly manage investments for pension funds and endowments), and then increasingly to hedge funds, private equity funds and venture capital funds, which charge much higher fees. We show that a large part of this [asset management revenue] growth is a simple consequence of rising asset values without commensurate declines in percentage fees.”
Given how much high-fee asset management is in the news, and somewhat envious discussions around faculty lunchrooms and university development offices, it is indeed surprising to learn that the more mundane business of providing consumer credit and residential mortgages, and charging transaction fees, contributed a larger increase in finance-sector revenue, at least up until 2007.  Proprietary trading profits don’t even make their list.

I won’t delve much into numbers, except to point out how hard measurement is. The difference between GDP, revenue, wages, employees, value added, etc. matters. We really want to know how many resources are devoted to the function of finance, but GDP is based on industry. If a steel company runs its pension fund investments in-house, that activity is counted as part of the steel industry GDP. If the steel company hires an asset management company to run its pension fund investments, now that same activity shows up as finance industry GDP.  If an individual shifts his investments to a mutual fund, his investment management activity shifts from home production, not counted at all, to market activity. GDP shows a larger finance industry, though overall resources devoted to money management may decline.  And data on the size of finance that ends in 2007 leads to an obvious retort – like the weather, if you don’t like it, just wait a bit.

Instead, let us take the broad brush of facts as Greenwood and Scharfstein have summarized them and think about how we should interpret those facts. (I pick on Greenwood and Scharfstein’s interpretations, but this isn’t really a comment on their paper. Their interpretations are a well-stated representative of a larger academic literature, especially Phillippon (2008), and a much larger public and policy debate. Greenwood and Scharfstein merely make a concise and specific reference point for a broader discussion.)

As Greenwood and Scharfstein note, there are many obviously beneficial aspects to the growth of finance over the last 40 years. My grandfather held individual shares of stock. I hold a share of the Vanguard total market index in a 401(k) plan, a much better diversified and much lower-cost form of investment. The much larger participation, diversification, and consequent risk-sharing, plausibly has led not only to better retirement savings opportunities, but to halving of the cost of capital for businesses that issue equity – price/earnings ratios seem to be on a permanently higher plateau, or at least so we hope. The accessibility of housing, student, and consumer finance has become if anything too easy.  Let’s instead focus on the contentious issues.

Their basic facts seem to scream: The demand for financial services shifted out.  People with scarce skills supplying such services made a lot of money.  (Portfolio managers, yes. Janitors and secretaries, no.) A system with proportional fees, a common structure in professional services, interacted with stock and home price increases (a different surge in demand) to produce increased revenue.  That fee rates did not fall seems hardly surprising when faced with a surge in demand.  Why demand shifted out, and why house and stock prices rose (temporarily, it turns out) are good questions. But they don’t have much to do with the structure of the finance industry.

Still, let us dig deeper. In particular, I wish to trace what the voluminous recent literature in finance implies for the “size” and “social benefits” question.

II. Active management and fees

a. The traditional view

High-fee active management and underlying active trading has been deplored by academic finance in the efficient-markets tradition for a generation.  French (2008) is a comprehensive summary.  French estimates that equity investors in aggregate, between 1980 and 2006, paid 0.67% per year in active management fees, which conservatively means 10% of the value of their investments.

French, and Greenwood and Scharfstein, note that the increase in management fee revenue lies on top of several offsetting trends. Individuals moved investments from direct holdings to mutual funds, and then to index or other passive and semi-passive funds[5]. Their participation overall increased, and new investors in defined-contribution plans invest almost exclusively in funds.

Mutual fund fee rates, came down sharply, in part reflecting the slow spread of very low-fee index and other passive funds, and in part simply reflecting competitive pressure. French reports that the average equity fund fee fell from 2.19% in 1980 to 1% in 2007. Greenwood and Scharfstein report that average bond fund fees fell from 2.04% to 0.75%  Some index funds charge as little as 0.07% .

Total mutual fund fee revenues reflect these declining rates multiplied by a much larger share of assets under management.  So, the behavior of individuals and funds oriented towards individuals does reflect sensible forces, if one is willing to grant a rather long time span for those forces to affect industry structure.

High-wealth individuals and institutions moved their investments to even more actively-managed hedge funds, private equity, venture capital, and other even higher-fee and more active investment vehicles. Hedge fund fee rates are reportedly stable over time with 1.5-2.5% management fee plus 15-25% “performance” fee; the fund managers keep 15-25% of the profits above a high-water mark. This part of the market surely offers the more puzzling behavior. Asness (2004) chalks fee stability up to supply and demand: more investors are looking for hedge funds (with great track records) than entrepreneurs are able to set up such funds.

That would all make some sense if investors were getting something for those fees. But the aggregate portfolio of equity mutual funds is almost exactly the value-weighted market portfolio, and the average alpha[6]  before fees is very nearly zero. (Fama and French (2010) is an excellent tip of this iceberg of research.)   The evidence from hedge funds, which struggles with much worse survivor-bias and multidimensional benchmarking issues, still ends up arguing over a few percentage points of alpha one way or the other, hardly the expected gold mine.

Mediocre average results might not be surprising. With free entry in any business, the average performer will be average. The average economics professor isn’t that good either. But one might expect that, as in every other field of human endeavor, the good managers would be reliably good. Every manager I’ve ever talked to responds “Sure, the average manager doesn’t know what he’s doing.  But we have alpha.” Michael Jordan’s past performance was a reliable indication of what would happen in the next game.

In this context, Fama and French’s (2010) more surprising finding is that the distribution of alpha is remarkably small. The sample of mutual fund alpha is only very slightly wider than what one would expect if nobody had any true alpha, and sample results were just due to luck. Fama and French’s  estimate (p. 1935) of the distribution of true alpha has a standard deviation of only 1.25% on an annual basis, meaning that only 16% of funds have true alphas (gross, before fees) of 1.25% or greater. And 16.5% have “true alphas” of negative 1.25% or worse.  Similarly, study after study finds that past performance, especially long-term average returns, has essentially no power to predict future performance. What persistence there is seems related to the small one-year autocorrelation in underlying stock returns, which random portfolios will inherit. (Carhart (1997)).

For 40 years, academic finance has deplored active investing and paying fees for active management. It seems the average investor should save himself 67 basis points a year and just buy a passive index such as Vanguard’s total market portfolio, and the stock pickers should do something more productive like drive cabs.  Active management and its fees seem like a total private, and social, waste.

b. A supply-demand view of active management and its fees

On second look, this hallowed view – and its antithesis -- reflect somewhat inconsistent positions.

Active management and active management fees have survived 40 years of efficient-markets disdain.  If a freshwater economist doesn’t accept “folly” for “explaining” patterns of predictable price movement that survive 40 years, how can he accept it to explain such a stable industry equilibrium?  From the other viewpoint,  the saltwater consensus that markets are inefficient, and prices are far from “fundamentals” because of various behavioral or limits-to-arbitrage frictions, implies that there is a lot of alpha and there ought to be a lot more (and better) active management. You can’t both deplore the inefficiency of the market and active management that attempts to correct it.

“Explaining” active management and fees as folly is certainly inconsistent with my methodological outline: Folly is a name for a residual, not a quantitatively successful theory of active management.

We are not, however, at sea with an unfathomable puzzle. Jonathan Berk and Richard Green (2004) have created a supply-demand economic model that explains many of the basic facts of mutual fund performance, flows, and fees.

Suppose that some fund managers do have alpha. Alpha, however, has diminishing returns to scale. Traders report that many strategies apply only to smaller stocks[7] or suffer from price impact if they are implemented on too large a scale.

As an example, suppose that a manager can generate 10% alpha on $10 million dollars.  Suppose also that his fees are a constant 1% of assets under management, and to make it simple assume the stock market value does not change. Thus, in his first year, the manager makes $1 million abnormal return. He pockets $100,000, (1%) and his investors get $900,000.

Seeing these good results, investors rush in. But the manager’s idea cannot scale past $10 million of assets, so the manager invests extra money in the index.  With $20 million under management, he still generates $1 milllion alpha on the first $10 milllion, and nothing on the rest.  He takes one percent of assets under management, now $200,000. But his investors still get $800,000 alpha. More investors pour in.

The process stops when the manager has $100 million under management. He still generates $1 million alpha, but now he collects $1 million in fees. His investors get exactly zero alpha, the competitive rate of return. But all are acting rationally[8].

This model explains many puzzling facts: In equilibrium, returns to investors are the same in active and passively managed funds.  Funds earn only enough alpha to cover their fees. Good past fund returns do not forecast good future returns.  Investors chase managers with good past returns anyway, one of the most-cited “irrational” puzzles about mutual funds.[9]  Returns to investors do not measure alpha. Fees do. Managers with good track records get paid a lot. 

This model doesn’t explain everything. It is predicated on the fee structure, and does not answer why the manager cannot simply charge $1 million fee to start with. (One might view the expansion of hedge funds as implementing exactly this fee innovation.)  Fama and French (2010) complain that the average alpha after fees is negative, but their benchmarks contain no transactions costs.

Still, this analysis is worth celebrating as an interesting step in the “normal science,” “work harder” response of research to puzzles.  After 40 years of unproductively deploring active management and its fees, it turns out a simple supply and demand story can explain many facts.

c. Is it silly to pay a proportional fee?

The fee structure of asset management is central to Greenwood and Scharfstein’s argument:
If the stock market doubles in value through price appreciation, there is no obvious reason why investment management services in the aggregate would be worth more, or would cost more to provide.
I’m tempted to say, “There you go again.” “No obvious reason” means “I don’t know” not “I know it’s too big.” But let’s deeper into this ubiquitous fee arrangement.

First, fee revenue is not a good measure of the “size” of finance. If you invest $10 million, agree to pay your hedge fund manager 2+20, and markets double, he pockets $2.2 million. If we followed the standard that we measure GDP in service industries by factor payments, we would call this $2.2 million of extra GDP, $2.2 million of “resources” devoted to “finance.”  Greenwood and Scharfstein do not to make this mistake – they call it revenue. But why do we care about revenue? Revenue is not the same thing as social resources consumed. In this case, it’s a pure transfer.  It’s better to think of the fee simply as a risk-sharing arrangement among co-investors.  We didn’t know that stocks would double in value. At best some measure of the discounted present value of fees should count.

Second, if the market doubled in value because everything else did – capital stock, earnings, etc. – then surely by constant returns to scale, the value of investment management (whatever it is) would also double.  Thus, if the argument is not just a repetition of the idea that fees should be zero, it must be that fees should not rise with higher valuations -- higher price/earnings ratios, lower discount rates -- in the same way fees should scale with rising cashflows.  As well as not being an obvious proposition, such rises in valuation are temporary. Just wait a moment.

Third, we have seen in fact a substantial decline in fee rates in mutual funds. The constant fee rate simply did not happen.

Last, and most of all, just what do we expect fees to look like? If the current fee structure seems to produce a “too large” finance sector, what’s the optimal contract? What’s the distortion?

Greenwood and Scharfstein mention cost, a reasonable benchmark in a competitive market.  Fees already scale with cost in the cross–section: mutual funds and hedge fund offer a schedule of lower fees for larger investments, which compensates the funds for the fixed costs of managing any account. So the complaint must be the time series: If you invest (say) $10,000, perhaps you should sign up for $100 per year fees regardless of performance? Why don’t we see this fee structure? One reason is regulation: mutual funds must treat all investors alike. They cannot charge a different fee rate to different vintages of investors. But the deeper reason is that contract is pretty obviously silly.  Since most people make monthly contributions, each contribution would have to have a different fee, a nightmare of accounting. Or do they think mutual funds should bill by the hour, passing on “cost” as lawyers do? It’s pretty clear why that doesn’t happen!

More deeply, percentage fees pervade professional services, and have done so basically forever. Real estate agents charge percentage fees, and do better when house prices are higher – this is Greenwood and Scharfstein’s second major source of the increasing (until 2007) size of finance. Architects charge percentage fees. Contingency fee lawyers take a percentage of winnings. Corrupt officials take percentage bribes. Salesmen get percentage commissions.

In sum, the argument “finance is too big” because fees based on a percentage of assets under management are a big distortion seems awfully strained. At least I’d like to see a specific claim what the alternative, realistic, and privately or socially optimal contract is!

And percentage fees are a standard optimal contract argument. For example, from footnote 6: 
Fixed percentage fees can be justified if one [investor and manager] believes that a manager has the ability to create alpha…. But this argument does not hold in the aggregate, since alpha is zero sum across investors. 
This argument is logically wrong. Alpha sums to zero over all investors. The managers may be the positive alpha investors, and individual investors the negative alpha investors.  Current empirical evidence suggests they are not for mutual funds, but it’s not impossible.

More importantly, in the end, then, the supposed irrationality of AUM fees comes down simply to the position that nobody should pay any fees at all for active management, because there is no alpha, not that something is fundamentally wrong with the AUM form of the fees. If Berk and Green are right, the whole argument falls apart.

d. Where’s the wedge? What is the optimal contract and why don’t we see it?

Let us follow the economists’ methodology instead. Rather than argue whether fees are too big or too small, too fixed or too variable, let us try to identify the distortion that drives the contract away from being optimal.  Greenwood and Scharfstein:
…there are significant distortions in the market for professional asset management arising from investor naiveté (mainly households) and agency problems associated with certain institutional investors (mainly pension funds). These distortions have led to increased use of active asset management and may also have biased active asset managers away from socially efficient forms of information acquisition and asset allocation.
… investor naiveté results in more active management and more expensive active management than in a world with sophisticated investors.
…Pension fund and endowment managers are presumably less naïve than households, but institutional factors and agency problems may lead them to overpay for active management
40 years of “naiveté” -- a new term in behavioral finance, as far as I can tell – strikes me as simply saying “we have no idea.”

Individual investors, many of whom actively manage their portfolios and whose decisions in doing so are the stuff many behavioral biases, may be doing a lot better with 1% active management fee than actively managing on their own. As a matter of fact, individual investors are moving from active funds to passive funds, and fees in each fund are declining. Many of their fee advisers are bundling more and more services, such as tax and estate planning, which easily justify fees. At least naiveté is declining over time.

Most of all, the naiveté argument is belied by the fact that large, completely unconstrained, and very sophisticated investors are moving to high-fee active management.

Despite the troubles of 2008 involving illiquid private equity and interest rate swaps[10], the Harvard endowment is in 2012 about 2/3 externally managed by fee investors[11],  and is 30% invested in “private equity” and “absolute return” (hedge funds).[12]  The University of Chicago endowment is similarly invested in private equity and “absolute return,”[13] and whatever qualms some of its curmudgeonly faculty express about alphas, fees, and active management are not shared by the endowment:[14]
 “The majority of TRIP’s [“Total Return Investment Portfolio] assets are managed by external managers specializing in a specific asset class, geography, or strategy. These asset managers outperformed their respective benchmarks in every asset class, adding over 500 basis points of performance versus the strategic benchmark.”
500 basis ponts of alpha.  Put that in your pipe and smoke it, Fama and French. At least we know one active manager’s perception of what they get for their fees.

I only pick on our endowments for fun, and to spark interest among a readership of academic economists. This general approach to portfolio management is pretty much standard at endowments, nonprofits, sovereign wealth funds, family offices, pension funds, and so forth – anywhere there is a big pot of money to invest: These investors pay a lot of attention to allocation among name-based buckets, as represented in the pie charts,  “domestic equity,” “international equity,” “fixed income,” “absolute return,” “private equity,” etc. Then, funds in these buckets are each allocated to a group of fee-based active managers, to deliver “alpha” within their style. 

This overall approach bears no resemblance to standard portfolio theory. Any allocation other than market weights is an active bet. Name buckets make no sense, betas and correlations do. (For example, international and domestic equity are very highly correlated.) And don’t even ask whether hedge fund manager A is shorting what B is buying, what happens to fees when you give a portfolio of managers 2+20 compensation, half of them win, while half lose, or even why we pay the growth manager to buy the same stock that the value manager just sold.

Anywhere else in economics, we would ask why people have evolved this widely-practiced set of rough and ready decision procedures.  Standard portfolio theory is, in fact, devilishly hard to apply in real-world situations, if one is not going to simply hold the market index.   But and vaguely-stated “agency problems” and “naviete” seem an unpersuasive as well as superficial explanation.

“Agency problems” means problems in the contract between those in charge – boards of directors and trustees, or the wealthy individual at the head of the family office – and the manager who in turn hires the other managers.  But this too is a story. Greenwood and Scharfstein neither explain nor cite a set of essential frictions (e.g. information or moral hazard), and how, as a result, a principal who wants to put it all in the Vanguard total-market index is forced to hire a manager who follows the above “standard” portfolio process.



Harvard's endowment was overseen by a high-powered board, including its president Larry Summers, probably the least naïve investor on the planet. The picture that Summers and his board, or the high-powered talent on Chicago's investment committee[15] are simply too naïve to demand passive investing, or that they really want the endowments to sit on the Vanguard total market index, but some "agency problem" with the managers they hire and fire with alacrity prevents that outcome from happening, simply does not wash. Just ask them. (I have.) This is exactly the portfolio and process that the people in charge want!  Perhaps the whole world is naïve, but then so are the designers and implementers of regulation when they, like Summers, go to Washington to correct matters.


Increasing naïveté and worsening “agency problems” seem even more dubious “explanations” for the increasing share of sophisticated investor’s portfolios in active high-fee investing. 

As for excessive compensation, in the first layer of fees (fees to the manager who pays fees to the other managers) Harvard endowment’s CIO Jane Mendillo was paid[16] $4.7 million, most of which was straight salary. The University of Chicago’s Mark Schmid gets only $1.8 million, though our measely $5.6 billion AUM relative to Harvard’s $27.6 billion may have something to do with it. If we’re paying this much, is it that much of a puzzle that pension funds do the same thing?

II. Where is the alpha, and the value of active trading

Fees are half the puzzle. The other half of the puzzle is, is there any alpha in the first place, and if so, why? Really, the argument over fees came down to the argument that there is no alpha, so nobody should pay any fees at all.  If there is alpha, the Berk and Green analysis suggests we may be on our way to understanding fees.  Much of the traditional disparagement of active management fees comes down to the view that markets do not permit anyone to earn abnormal expected returns, so active trading itself is a waste of time.

The average investor theorem is an important benchmark in evaluating this question:  The average investor must hold the value-weighted market portfolio.  Alpha, relative to the market portfolio, is by definition a zero-sum game.  For every investor who overweights a security or invests in a fund that does so, and earns alpha, some other investor must underweight the same security, and earn the same negative alpha.   We can’t even collectively rebalance: If the stock market goes up, so that stocks represent 80% of wealth and bonds 20%, rather than previous 60% - 40% weights, we cannot all sell stocks to reestablish 60/40 weights. For each investor who rebalances, some other investor must overweight stocks even more.  Finally, each of us can protect ourselves from being the negative-alpha mark with a simple strategy: hold the market portfolio, and refuse to trade away from it, no matter what price is offered.

a. Alpha. Lots of alpha.

Alpha seems a dicey proposition. But the last 20 years of finance research is as clear as empirical research in economics can be: There is alpha, at least relative to the market portfolio, lots of it, and all over the place.  (Cochrane (2011) is one summary of this huge literature; I won’t cite each fact separately.)

A slew of “anomaly” strategies generate average returns but do not have large market betas, and so represent “alpha” relative to the market portfolio. Examples include small stocks, value stocks (low market value relative to book value; high “q”), momentum stocks (those that have risen in the previous year),  stocks of companies that repurchase shares, stocks with high accruals, and stocks with low betas. The carry trade in maturities, currencies and credit (buy high yield securities, sell low yield securities), and writing options, especially the “disaster insurance” of out of the money put options, also generates alpha. Expected market returns are not constant, but vary over time by as much as their roughly 6% mean and more. The yields to the anomaly strategies also vary over time, further suggesting dynamic trading strategies as well as allocations to assets different from market weights.

The “financial constraints,” “financial frictions,” “institutional finance” “price pressure” and “limits to arbitrage” literatures go a step further.  Especially when leveraged intermediaries are stressed, prices of nearly identical securities can become large.  For example, during the financial crisis, corporate bonds traded at higher prices than their synthetic versions consisting of a treasury bond and a credit default swap.  Covered interest parity failed – you could earn a larger return by buying euros, investing in European money markets, and converting back to dollars in the futures markets than by investing in US money markets. More generally, these literatures find evidence for “fire sales,” when stressed intermediaries try to dump large portfolios of assets on the market.

Most of these strategies also correspond to broad categories of common movement among securities. For example, if one buys a portfolio of “value” (low price) stocks in the hope of reaping the “value” alpha without risk, one soon discovers the tendency of all value stocks to rise and fall together, leaving risk in this portfolio. Unlike the conventional concept of an “inefficiency” alpha which diversifies away across multiple investments, the “value” alpha requires one to take on additional dimensions of undiversifiable risk.

In this way, these strategies represent additional (beyond the market) dimensions of “systematic” risk. For example, Fama and French (2006) summarize the expected returns to value stocks by their varying exposures to a “value factor,” leaving no alpha in a multifactor model. But the value factor represents alpha relative to the market portfolio.

Many of the time-varying risk premiums (expected returns) also rise and fall together. The financial crisis was a great time to buy any number of risky investments.

The broad brush of facts are not really under debate. Their interpretation is. First, they might indicate old-fashioned informational inefficiency – information, such as inside information, that somebody has, but is not fully reflected in market prices, for technical or behavioral reasons. The common movement of returns makes this argument harder to swallow, however.

Second, they might reflect imperfect risk sharing and (often temporary) market segmentation: information is fully incorporated in market prices, but, especially at high frequency, some risks are narrowly held, so command higher risk premiums then they would if all of us were able to participate fully.  If the usual arbitrageurs are not around or able to bid aggressively, prices may fall further than they would otherwise, or if all of us were participating directly.

Third, they might reflect the multidimensional and time-varying nature of risk premiums in a fully integrated and informationally-efficient market. The capital asset pricing model was built on evidently untrue assumptions, after all, that the world presents iid shocks, risk premiums are constant over time, and the average investor does not have a job, real estate, or other non-marketed capital.

b. Implications of alpha

For our purposes, we do not really have to take a stand on which of these explanations carries the most weight. For the facts alone, and any of the interpretations, have important implications for the size of finance in general and the size of active management in particular.

The first and especially the second explanation, which is the heart of the “credit constraints,” “limits to arbitrage” and “institutional finance” literatures, imply directly that finance is too small. If information is not being incorporated into market prices, to such an extent that simple strategies with big alphas can be published in the Journal of Finance, it follows directly that there are not enough arbitrageurs.  If assets are falling in “fire sales,” there are not enough fire-sale buyers following the fire trucks around. If credit constraints are impeding the flow of capital, we need to invest social resources into loosening those constraints.  (To be precise, these facts document potential benefits to a larger finance sector. There are also costs, and one has to see if the benefits outweigh the costs. But establishing some benefits to enlargement of finance is surprising enough.)

Many of these puzzles suggest needed investments in institutional development, not just an expansion of existing structures. As a concrete and recent example, consider the “betting against beta” anomaly recently reexamined by Frazzini and Pedersen (2011a,b). Frazzini and Pedersen document that low beta stocks get higher average returns than they should, and high beta stocks get lower returns than they should. Their interpretation is that many investors want more risk than the market portfolio provides (half should, by the average investor theorem), yet leverage is costly to obtain. These investors buy high-beta stocks instead, driving up the prices of these stocks. “Let them buy options, and leveraged ETFs” you might say, but Frazzini and Petersen show the same patterns in these vehicles.

This is a narrowly-held risk explanation. Arbitrageurs cannot help: Correcting market prices through better risk sharing needs a mass of investors to change their portfolios and bear more risk.  To bring prices back to what they should be, we need low-cost vehicles to bring  high-beta investments to the half of the investing public who wants them.

We have seen this before. Small stocks were the first big anomaly relative to the CAPM, generating (it appeared) higher average returns than their betas justified. But it was very hard for individual investors to hold a diversified portfolio of small stocks. Arbitrageurs could only do so much, because small stocks move together, so a concentrated portfolio bears undiversifiable risk.  Small stock funds were started, which allowed a mass of investors to participate.  Those funds fees and expenses now contributed to revenue and measured GDP, in the way that the activities of individual investors holding small stocks did not. But they allowed the risk of small stocks to be widely shared, and the small stock premium to decline.

c. Multidimensional risk-sharing: A different view of markets and active management

The presence of dozens of “systematic” sources of risk, beyond the market, with substantial and time-varying premiums, has deep implications for asset management, no matter what the ultimate general-equilibrium source of these phenomena, in particular even if they result from time-varying macroeconomic risk and not frictions or inefficiencies. After all, if tomatoes are expensive today, you should put fewer of them in your salad. It doesn’t matter whether the sale comes from a “rational” bad harvest, or an “irrational” bubble in the tomato futures market.  Likewise, it behooves an investor to see what risks are on sale today, no matter what their source, or have his manager do so. 

The conventional disdain of management is rooted in the conventional view of the investment environment, which predated these discoveries. This view describes one source of “systematic” risk, accessible through passive investments: the market portfolio of risky assets. The investor understands this opportunity, and knows how much market risk he wishes to take.  Returns are independent over time, so he does not often reconsider his “systematic” risk exposure. If he hires fee managers, their job is to earn “alpha.” In turn, alpha is interpreted only as return available from exploiting “inefficiency,” information the manager has that is not reflected in market prices, diversifiable across individual bets, and winnings from zero-sum gambling with other active managers.  In this conventional view, the investor does not need to hedge the risks of job, business, outside income, or peculiar liability stream he is trying to fund.

But we have learned that this view of the world is completely wrong.  Standard mean-variance (alpha-beta) portfolio advice is upended by the facts as they have emerged.  Perhaps some of puzzling investment practice might be understood as a rough and ready way of adapting to the world as it is.

In a time-varying world, long-term investment is quite different from short-term investment. As a simple example, consider the riskless asset. A short-term investor holds a money-market fund as his riskless asset, and stays away from long-term bonds. To a long-term investor, by contrast, a long-term indexed bond is the “riskless” investment, exactly the opposite result, and money-market funds expose him to interest-rate risk. The long-term investor does not care about temporary price fluctuations of long-term bonds, as he knows the bond’s value is always the same at his horizon. Now to integrate this fact into the conventional short-horizon perspective, we say that the long-term investor values long-term bonds – despite their terrible one-year mean-variance properties, as a “state-variable hedging” asset.

Most investors also have jobs, businesses, or other non-marketeable income streams or fixed liabilities. Such investors should buy assets hedge those streams, and to hedge state variables for those streams. You want a portfolio that rises when there is bad news about your future income, before the bad future incomes arrive. University endowments supporting tenured professors have a risky asset stream, a bond-like liability stream leveraged by tax-arbitrage borrowing, and an important tournament relative to other universities in their objective functions (Goetzmann and Oster 2012). Pension funds have, well, pensions.

In turn, this time-varying desire to hedge outside income and state variable risk are prime candidates for economic explanations of the fact that equilibrium asset returns do not obey the static CAPM. If so, all this dynamic trading represents dynamic, socially beneficial insurance.

Now, none of this is easy. Merton (1971) described hedging demands 40 years ago, but even with thousands of following papers, academic portfolio theory really does not offer real-world advice. (See Cochrane 2012 for a long exposition.)

Even to a one-period mean-variance investor, taking advantage of time-varying multidimensional risks (being the insurance-writer) takes technical knowledge. Do you know how to write a CDS contract, get a stock momentum strategy to work without drowning in transactions costs, take advantage of temporarily high put option premiums in the Eurozone, or even reliably buy a “value” portfolio? 

The nature and amount of multidimensional systematic risk one should take is much more nebulous and difficult to assess than the traditional question, how much market risk one should take. Have you even thought about whether you should be writing put options? Or maybe you should be buying them, as you buy home insurance, despite the premium?

Well, if it’s not easy, portfolio problems like this might certainly benefit from professional and specialized management, and such management ought to be able to charge a fee.

Hedge funds seem designed to serve this investment world. They can move to and from asset classes as risk premiums change, and by using leverage and derivatives they can alter overall exposures quickly without incurring the huge transactions cost of buying and selling large portfolios. (Why a portfolio of hedge funds makes sense is less clear.)

But in this dynamic buying and selling of multiple dimensions of risk, I do not need to invoke informational “inefficiency” at all, or violate the average investor theorem.  Warren Buffett might write a lot of put options (he is), responding to a higher premium, because Chicago is buying them (it is), presumably responding to a risk analysis of the effect of another crash on its operations.

This radically different view of the investment environment, and portfolio formation in that environment certainly explodes the traditional view that disparages active management. I do not claim that current portfolio practice, and especially hiring many different high-fee hedge funds, is necessarily an optimal response. But it isn’t necessarily as “naïve” or “agency conflicted” as it otherwise seems, given we really have no concrete better advice to offer.

d. Marketing

In the quest to explain the persistence of active management and its fees, a second analogy seems worth pursuing: marketing.

Marketing and advertising have long been a puzzle to economists, Consumer Reports readers and coupon-clippers everywhere. Why buy the brand name when the generic is just as good – often nearly identical – and costs a lot less?

Theorem one of the frictionless theory of finance (the Modigilani-Miller theorem) says that the value of marketing is zero.  The value of a portfolio is the value of its ingredients.  Yet the money-management industry is essentially a marketing industry: They take the most generic and easily available ingredients you can think of, put them in a package, wrap a nice label on it, and market like crazy. Yes, from this point of view, it’s puzzling that people don’t buy the generic (Vanguard). It’s puzzling that they don’t buy the pieces and assemble their own (etrade).  It’s puzzling that they pay quite so much for the slight differences in ingredients that the active managers or closed-end funds deliver. As it is puzzling that they pay for Coke, Clorox, Bayer, or bottled water; that they shop at Macys not Target, Whole Foods not Costco, and a hundred other brand names.

It’s not the time to digress into the “rationality” of the entire field of marketing and advertising. But dismissing centuries worth of branding and advertising as simply “naïveté” and folly seems, well, naïve.  And perhaps by thinking of mutual fund management as an instance of this larger pattern, we may make some progress to understanding how it actually works. 

III. The value of information trading

Much trading, and active management, however, is clearly aimed at bringing information to the market, not just better sharing time-varying multiple dimensions of risk or overcoming segmentation. Let us reconsider the social value of that activity.

Aren’t all resources devoted to a zero-sum game ipso-facto socially wasted? Aren’t half of the people who don’t index, by definition, deluded? Do we have to rely, as we must in defending the casino industry, on an entertainment value for trading?

No. The social point of information trading is “price discovery.” If someone has a piece of information, he buys on that information and his “price impact” makes prices reflect that information.

Thus, as French (2008) recognizes, there is a plausible argument here too that not enough social resources are devoted to price discovery, since it is a public good:
In aggregate, active investors almost certainly improve the accuracy of financial prices. This, in turn, improves society’s allocation of resources. Thus, my estimate of the cost of active investing also measures society’s cost of price discovery.
I offer no evidence on whether society is buying too little or too much of this good. Price discovery, however, is an externality—each active investor pays the full cost of his efforts but captures only a tiny slice of the benefit—so there is no reason to think active investors purchase the optimal amount of price discovery.
The common complaint “the financial crisis proves markets aren’t efficient” is at heart, paradoxically, a complaint that there was not enough active information-based trading. “Efficiency” means that prices incorporate available information.  All a more “efficient” stock market or mortgage-backed security market could have done is to fall sooner. (It’s a complaint, not a proof – one can argue that markets were efficient, failing only to be clairvoyant, as runs are by definition unpredictable.  The word “efficiency” is often misused by people who do not understand its definition. I once told a newspaper reporter that I thought markets were pretty “efficient,” and he quoted me as saying markets are “self-regulating!”) 

The literature on short-selling is revealing to this point. Actively-trading short sellers uncover far more financial fraud than the SEC, whose performance in the Bernie Madoff case is more typical than you might think. Some of the biggest and most uncontroversial alphas and “inefficiencies” – prices that do not incorporate available information – occur when there is an impediment, technical or regulatory, to the activities of these short sellers.  Lamont (2004) finds 2.4% monthly alpha to a portfolio of short-selling constrained stocks, probably the clearest and largest clear informational “inefficiency” around except for inside information.  This is a concrete example of inadequate (because constrained) trading.

Greenwood and Scharfstein also explain this point well:
From a social benefit perspective, however, the critical question is not whether active management leads to excess returns—it does not. [On average, in mutual funds.] Rather what matters is whether the pursuit of excess returns produces socially valuable information.
So, the question is whether we want prices to be more efficient. Is this useful?
The social benefits from efficient markets are difficult to measure. One of the main benefits is that firms can raise new capital at prices that accurately reflect their fundamental value, i.e, that they can raise money in primary markets to fund real investments.
Without speculators evaluating Google’s plans and driving the price to stratospheric levels, Google could not have issued stock to fund investments in, say, driverless cars. Certainly, this kind of investment would not be supported by bank lending.

But,
Of course, much information discovery is oriented toward trading securities in secondary markets, i.e., trading securities that already exist.
This is a good point. IPOs, venture capital, and private equity are important functions of finance, but they do not depend on information trading in established markets.

Having an efficient secondary-market price if established firms want to issue additional equity and invest is useful, however.  Unlike Greenwood and Scharfstein, I see in the strong correlations between stock prices and investment, over time (through the tech boom and bust of the 1990s and through the financial crisis), and across industries (Google vs., say, GM), a validation of the Q theory of investment (Cochrane (1991), (2011) Figure 10), so long as you don’t difference the data too much.  To dismiss the value of efficient markets because a few alternative regressions find that variables other than Q help to predict investment – and in the absence of a compelling theory why investment should be disconnected from asset markets, for the large, unconstrained, firms who regularly access those markets and account for the bulk of investment – seems again to take a puzzle as fact a bit too quickly.

But the whole cacophony of trading still seems like a lot of effort for this small goal. And, as Greenwood and Scharfstein point out, it’s hard to see why we need high frequency trading
For example, a hedge fund may be willing to pay $20,000 to form a more accurate prediction of a company’s earnings to be released in the next week… in an exchange economy without production,… the $20,000 is a social loss because getting this information into prices one week earlier is unlikely to lead to a more efficient allocation of real resources.
I.e., the firm is unlikely to issue equity during the week. This is an important example to think about.

Here, I think Greenwood and Scharfstein miss a second main function of asset markets: risk sharing. Efficient markets have social value, even in an endowment economy. For example, if I own tree A, and you own tree B, we want to sell each other shares of the trees in order to share risk. An inefficient market will impede this process. You can increase utility without changing production, by changing the allocation of production.

More generally, the attractiveness of stocks to fundamental investors – the ones who did fund the initial public offering – depends on the stocks’ liquidity, the confidence that these investors can quickly sell those stocks at the “right” price when they feel like exiting. The whole rationale for most securities market regulation – even regulation that makes markets less efficient, such as the ban on insider trading -- is precisely this idea that the retail investor should face a “fair” and liquid market is based on this idea.

And we all see the advantage of less volatile markets. Yet it is exactly the activities of traders, such as in Greenwood and Scharfstein’s example, which minimize volatility. Any predictable price movement – any violation of the random walk – adds volatility.

The view that trading is socially beneficial only if it directly finances “real” investment, if taken seriously, would imply dramatic changes in asset markets. Most derivatives are clearly zero-sum, zero-net supply bets.  The dangerous idea that credit default swap trading should be banned except by holders of the underlying security would follow.  Political prediction markets, recently endorsed by perhaps the most distinguished set of coauthors ever to write an economics article (Arrow et. al (2008)), ought to be banned (as the CFTC just did).

Interestingly, markets dreamed up by economists to benefit risk sharing – such as Robert Shiller’s GDP futures markets, or hurricane catastrophe options – do poorly. Liquidity for risk-sharing investors seems to depend on the presence of high-frequency information traders.

Yet Greenwood and Scharfstein’s example is telling. To make it more vivid, suppose that the fund got the earnings announcement 5 minutes before release. “Price impact” is nebulous, but in the efficient-market extreme that it can buy all it wants, the firm could appropriate the entire increase in company value – and more, in options markets – based on the information. In turn, it would be willing to expend real resources covering almost all that value in order to get the information. Which clearly is a social waste – having the price rise (if it does!) 5 minutes earlier is not worth expending the entire change in value of the firm.

I conclude that information trading of this sort sits at the conflict of two externalities / public goods. On the one hand, as French points out, “price impact” means that traders are not able to appropriate the full value of the information they bring, so there can be too few resources devoted to information production (and digestion, which strikes me as far more important). On the other hand, as Greenwood and Scharfstein point out, information is a non-rival good, and its exploitation in financial markets is a tournament (first to use it gets all the benefit) so the theorem that profits you make equal the social benefit of its production is false. It is indeed a waste of resources to bring information to the market a few minutes early, when that information will be revealed for free a few minutes later.  Whether we have “too much” trading, too many resources devoted to finding information that somebody already has in will be revealed in a few minutes, or “too little” trading, markets where prices go for long times not reflecting important information, as many argued during the financial crisis, seems like a topic which neither theory nor empirical work has answered with any sort of clarity.

b. The puzzle of information trading

The process by which trading brings information to markets is still a bit of a mystery -- or, better, an active area of research on which we might be finally making fundamental progress.  And we should understand that process before pronouncing on the value of the resources it consumes, and even more so before advocating regulations such as transactions taxes to reduce trading volume (or, just as likely, transactions subsidies to increase it!)

The classic theory of finance predicts that information is perfectly reflected in prices, with no trading volume.  Every uninformed investor holds exactly the market index. He only buys and sells the entire index, when he wants to save or consume.  In part, this is his defense against being the negative-alpha half of the average-investor theorem. Anyone offering to trade individual stocks must know something.

And if the “uninformed” investors would only behave this way, then informed investors could make no money from their information. French’s public good analysis is perfect.

Suppose Apple is trading at $500 per share, but you know that the iphone 6 is going to be a great product and make Apple worth $1000 per share.  If you approach the index investor with an offer to buy Apple at $600 per share, he answers “no, I only buy and sell the entire index at one time.” If you offer $700, he answers “I don’t think you heard me. I only buy and sell the entire index.”  You can keep trying, bidding the price up all the way to an offer of $1000 per share, at which point you give up. The price rises, reflecting your information, but no trade occurred. (This is a colloquial version of Milgrom and Stokey’s (1982) “No Trade Theorem.”)

Prices reflect information with zero trading volume and zero profits for informed investors. Once again, the classic theory of finance is dramatically at odds with the facts. Yet the facts are so durable that “folly” seems hardly persuasive, and in any case a poor predictor of the fascinating patterns we see in empirical work on volume and trading patterns.

The classic theory also ignores costs. If information traders cannot earn positive alpha, and, if producing information and trading on it takes any time and resources, the information traders won’t bother, and nobody is left to make prices reflect information in the first place.  So, as Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) wrote, informationally efficient markets are impossible. Markets must be just inefficient enough to provide rewards for price discovery. But how? How do we overturn the no-trade theorem?  Why are any of us “passive” investors are willing to take the other side of the “active” investors and suffer negative alphas?

Models of information trading posit “liquidity traders,” who take positions in individual securities for unspecified reasons. But who are they, really? Other models (Scheinkman and Xiong (2003) for example) posit slightly-irrational dogmatic beliefs, to unwind the recursion by which if you make an offer to me, I update my view of the asset’s value and refuse to trade. Then we can have markets with traders, each of which does believe he’s smarter than average. Many trading models, such as Acharya and Pedersen (2005) simply write down overlapping generations of agents without bequests who die every two days or so, to force them to trade. All these assumptions are obviously convenient shortcuts for getting trading into the model for other purposes, such as studying liquidity, but they are not really fundamental descriptions of the trading and price-discovery process.

Yet the fact staring us in the face is that “price-discovery,” the process by which information becomes embedded in market prices, in our world, uses a lot of trading volume, and a lot of time, effort and resources (GDP).

The empirical literature offers many tantalizing glimpses. There is often a period after a news announcement, of high price volatility and trading volume, in which markets seem to be fleshing out what the news announcement actually means for the value of the security. For example, Lucca and Moench (2012) Figure 6 show an enormous spike in stock-index trading volume and price volatility in the hours just after the Federal Reserve announcements of scheduled Open Market Committee interest-rate decisions. The information is perfectly public. But the process of the market digesting its meaning, aggregating the opinions of its traders, and deciding what value of the stock index should be with the new information, seems to need not just bidding, but actual shares to trade hands.  (Banerjee and Kremer (2010) and Kim and Verrecchia  (1991) offer models in which “disagreement” about public information leads to trading volume.)   Perhaps the whole model of information, we all agree on the deck of cards, just not knowing which one was picked, is wrong.

Securities such as “on the run” or benchmark bonds, where “price discovery” takes place have higher prices than otherwise identical securities. Traders are willing to suffer lower average returns in order to participate in the information-trading game, in much the same way as money holders suffer lower returns for the transactions services money provides. (Cochrane (2003).) 

The markets we see are set up, and exist, almost entirely to be markets for information trading. They are not markets for securities. We could easily handle individual’s lifetime saving and dissaving needs, and firms’ need to issue and retire equity, in much sleepier institutions such as a bank.  Exchanges exist to facilitate price discovery, and that discovery comes with a vast amount of trading.  Options were invented largely to facilitate information trading – highly leveraged positions without defaults. And they have existed this way, for hundreds of years.  Though we may not yet understand how it works, is the existence of the NYSE and its volume of trading ipso-facto testament to human folly and naïveté?  How do folly and naïveté begin to explain the interesting empirical patterns?

Yes, we could each avoid being the negative alpha trader subsidizing this whole bit by indexing.  It’s a bit of a puzzle that we don’t.  It’s a good thing we don’t, or there would be no traders making prices efficient. And, before we deplore, it’s worth remembering just how crazy passive indexing sounds to any market participant. “What,” they might respond, “would you walk in to a wine store and say `I can’t tell good from bad, and the arbitrageurs are out in force. Just give me one of everything?’”

c. High-frequency trading and market-making

As we think about the vast bulk of trading, and high-frequency trading in particular, however, I think that Greenwood and Scharfstein’s insightful example, and the vast literature it represents, is fundamentally misleading.

The amount of trading that is actually based on a well-understood, “fundamental,” piece of information about a company’s cashflow is minuscule. Models in which an informed trader posesses a “signal” about the value of a liquidating dividend just don’t describe the vast majority of trading. High frequency traders do not make money by trading on earnings reports 20 milliseconds ahead of the market.

High frequency traders – and even most “low frequency” day and week traders -- look at patterns of prices, volumes, and past trading activity, not signals about firm fundamentals.  Their “information” consists of something else.  If you ask them, they say they are acting as “market makers,” “liquidity providers,” making money off the bid-ask spread offered to uninformed “liquidity traders,” and trying hard to stay out of the way of the few traders that do have real “fundamental” information. If you ask their critics, they are artfully front-running demand from less sophisticated investors, removing “liquidity” and worsening “price impact,” i.e. removing the economic rewards to genuine information trading, worsening French’s “public good” problem and simply stealing from informed and liquidity traders.

However we come to understand these issues, the social costs and benefits of high frequency trading are clearly not at all related to the minor (as a fraction of GDP) resources devoted to them – the cost of useless fiber-optic cable, co-located servers, and the time of smart programmers who could be developing better iphone games.  The social question for high-frequency trading is whether it screws up markets, or whether it provides needed “market-making” services.

There really isn’t much evidence (or solid theory) as yet. Isolated events lead me to some suspicion of “liquidity provision.”  In the widely reported May 6 2010 “flash crash,” the S&P 500 fell 6% in a few minutes after a large e-mini index sell order arrived, and promptly recovered in less than an hour. (See Kirilenko, Kyle, Samadi, and Tuzun (2011) Figure 1. ) On July 19, 2012 Coke, McDonalds,  IBM  and Apple saw price sawtooths: sharp rises exactly on each hour, reversed by the next hour. These were widely attributed to an algorithm placing big orders exactly on the hour – and other algorithms not picking up on the inefficient signal abundantly obvious to the human eye. (See Vigna and Lauricella (2012) for some excellent graphs.)  www.nanex.net/FlashCrash/OngoingResearch.html is a whole website devoted to weird behavior in high-frequency markets.  These are palpable inefficiencies, and suggest a market with very little “liquidity provision,” not the opposite. Weller (2012) shows that “fundamental” orders pass through chains of as many as 10 high frequency traders, and presents a model in which this chain is a way to “provide liquidity.”

A “government failure” may be partly to blame. The regulators (SEC, CFTC) require that prices must jump in discrete intervals – once 1/8 dollar, now 1 cent. They require that limit orders are fulfilled in time order: if order A arrives before order B, order A must get filled completely and B gets nothing. But regulators do not discretize time, as they discretize price. A need only get there a nanosecond before B to get the entire order. (Rather than placing orders quickly, the ability to cancel limit orders that are in the back of the line if execution starts to be “too fast” may be one of the advantages of very high speed.) These rules may have made sense in the era of human traders, and came unglued with electronic trading.

The incentive to spend too much money on speed in this game is obvious.  As is a solution (if my hunch proves correct by more careful theory and empirical work):  Suppose that an exchange operated on a discrete clock, as a computer does. It could run a once-per-second, or even once-per-minute, or once-per-hour matching process. Within the time interval, limit orders accumulate. They are not shown, so that responding to the order book does not become the new game. Then orders are matched once per second, with all orders received during the second treated equally. If there are more buy than sell at the crossing price, orders are filled proportionally. 

Such an exchange would eliminate high frequency trading. Now there would be no need to act faster than a second. Would it work better, and not have other problems? Would exchanges choose such systems if they were allowed to? Is there a force (the powerful influence of high-speed traders) that would keep exchanges from adopting such systems voluntarily, so it would have to be imposed by regulation?  The Taiwan stock exchange already matches limit orders once every 90 seconds. (Barber, Lee, Liu, and Odean (2009).) Is its performance atrociously worse?  These are all good questions.

IV. Housing, consumer credit, and the size of regulated finance

The facts revolving around the size of housing finance seem much easier to digest.  The big increase came in fees associated with residential loan origination and refinancing.

Once again, much of this increase seems easily digested as the response to an increase in demand. The increase in demand – the housing boom – may indeed not have been “socially optimal.” (!)  Here, Greenwood and Scharfstein echo many other critics of government policy for stoking the housing boom: “…the U.S. tax code – mainly through the mortgage interest deduction – already biases households towards investments in housing over other types of investments. Making mortgage credit cheaper and more available may have just exacerbated this bias.” Add low interest rates, the community reinvestment act, Fannie and Freddie, and the whole sordid cast of characters.

Still, should we fault an industry for reacting to an increase in demand? How much excess social size of finance here is fundamentally a “government failure?”

The large fees collected for refinancing mortgages (rather than originating and securitizing them) are a bit more puzzling.  US mortgages are strangely complicated, and quite different from mortgages around the world. We feature fixed-rate mortgages with no prepayment penalty, and a complex refinancing option that requires reassessment of the property, fees, points, and therefore consumers to solve a complex option-exercise problem. We could surely do things more simply. But not to digress too much, collecting fees when interest rates decline or consumers exercise the option to lower housing equity is not GDP, (except to the extent that the fees represent time required to fill out endless forms), it’s simply collecting on the complex terms of an option contract.

Now, that’s not the whole story, as there was a lot of financial innovation surrounding mortgage finance, some of which notoriously exploded.  “We raise concerns about the… fragility of the shadow banking system that facilitated this expansion.”  Me too. And once again, fragility is the issue, not share of GDP.

A concrete example may help. A mortgage-backed security is a pool of mortgages. Suppose that such securities were bundled together into mutual funds, held at floating value or exchange-traded, just like equities, in your and my retirement accounts and our endowments’ investments. This structure would be a terrific financial innovation. Though mortgage-backed securities are a bit opaque, they are nowhere near as opaque as the entire balance sheet of, say, Citigroup. So, the monitoring and information functions we ask investors to play are much easier for a pool of mortgages than for Citigroup equity. Furthermore, such a structure would be immune to runs, bankruptices, needs for bailouts and so forth, just as equities are. The fees required to fill out the mortgage-backed security paperwork vs. the costs of bank paperwork are a tiny issue.

Now, this is not what fell apart in the financial crisis. Mortgage-backed securities and their “tranches” were held, not by floating-NAV mutual funds, but in “special purpose vehicles,” funded by rolling over very short-term debt. This structure looks like a traditional bank, whose assets are mortgages and whose liabilities are short-term debt, bank deposits. With a big exception: where is the equity, which is supposed to bear losses in the event the assets don’t work out so well?

The answer is, that the special purpose vehicles also had an off-balance-sheet guarantee from sponsoring banks. So the banks really were holding credit risk after all. But regulations did not place capital requirements on off-balance-sheet guarantees. So one function of the whole “shadow bank” was to create an actual “bank,” but evade capital requirements.

Whether or not we spent a bit more or less of GDP filling out forms and paying fees for these structures is clearly the least of its problems. The shadow bank was prone to a textbook systemic run, which is what happened.

Now, what category of problem is this? Is it an externality, public good, asymmetric information or other “market failure?” No, this seems like a clear case of “government failure,” unintended consequences of poorly structured regulation. A question for another day is whether multiplying by a factor of 10 the size of the regulatory structure – at considerable cost in resources – will prevent or exacerbate this problem. At least we know where the problem lies.

V. Runs, “shadow banking,” and the size of transactions finance.

The mention of “shadow banking” brings up a long literature on the “size of finance” that has not been mentioned yet. The issues go by the words “welfare costs of inflation,” or “optimum quantity of money,” but the central issue is the same.

As captured in the Baumol-Tobin model, we economize on money holdings by making lots of trips to the bank. But those trips are a waste of social resources. If money paid interest, or if the nominal interest rate were zero, we could avoid them all, along with the bank employees and ATM machines that service those trips.  Robert Lucas (2000) put the point well:
In a monetary economy, it is in everyone's private interest to try to get someone else to hold non-interest-bearing cash and reserves. But someone has to hold it all, so all of these efforts must simply cancel out. All of us spend several hours per year in this effort, and we employ thousands of talented and highly-trained people to help us. These person-hours are simply thrown away, wasted on a task that should not have to be performed at all.
High interest rate (high inflation) countries spend notoriously large resources on money changing and banking services in an effort to reduce interest costs.

Lucas (2000) approaches the question, not by adding up estimates of the services used to avoid holding money as we have, but by calculating the area under the M1 demand curve. He concludes that “the gain from reducing the annual inflation rate from 10 percent to zero is equivalent to an increase in real income of slightly less than one percent.” “Finance” under a 10 percent inflation rate is “too big” by 1% of GDP, from this clear distortion.

Lucas did not go further to estimate the benefits of reducing the nominal interest rate to zero, as when he wrote there was not much data from this regime.  Depending on the rate of increase of money demand as interest rates go to zero, the area under the demand curve can be enormous. The fact that banks have increased excess reserves from about $6 billion to about $2 trillion as interest rates have fallen essentially to zero suggests that large welfare costs may have been the case.

In this context, part of the function of the “shadow banking system,” special-purpose vehicles,  auction-rate securities, overnight repurchase agreements, or money market funds with risky assets (Reserve fund’s large Lehman holdings), like that of the old-fashioned banking system which created deposits, was that its liabilities were, to investors, cash-alternative assets – fixed value, first-come-first-serve accounts, paying some interest greater than zero. Rather than focus on its assets, mortages or mortgage-backed securities, perhaps we should focus on the optimal size, social benefits and costs of these liabilities.

Shadow-banking securities allow investors to avoid the needless interest costs of holding money, which is socially useful.  But there is a better way to achieve the same outcome:  a zero nominal rate, or money that pays interest. Relative to that benchmark, the costs of setting up the shadow banking system, for the purpose of providing interest-paying money, are wasted. More importantly, shadow-banking assets are prone to runs, which is an order of magnitude larger social cost.

In any case, following the 2007-2008 financial crisis, and perhaps more importantly the collapse of short-term interest rates to zero and the innovation that bank reserves pay interest, this form of “shadow banking” has essentially ceased to exist. RIP. 

To drive home this point (and to complain about any analysis of the size of finance that stops in 2007), here are two graphs representing the size of the “shadow banking system,” culled from other papers. From Adrian and Ashcraft (2012, p. 24), the size of the securitized debt market (whose demise I regret – the problem is not securitizing debt but funding that asset with run-prone short-term liabilities)



And from Gorton and Metrick (2012), a different slice of securitized debt markets:



Furthermore, we could easily insure that the unstable parts of “shadow banking” do not come back. We can live the Friedman optimal quantity of money. The Fed can continue to pay market rates on reserves, even as interest rates rise. The Treasury can expand its plan to issue floating-rate debt, to issue floating-rate, fixed-value debt. This debt works like a money market fund: it has a constant redemption value of 1.00, interest is set on a floating basis, perhaps monthly.

Our economy can be costlessly satiated in liquidity. No resources at all need to be directed to economizing on the use of liquid assets, no resources at all need to be directed to the creation of private substitutes for interest-paying government money. The remaining interest cost of money applies only to actual cash, most of which is held overseas or illegally anyway. (US currency outstanding is about $1 trillion, which divided by 300 million is $3,300 per person, and 75% of which is $100 bills. What’s in your wallet?) And no resources need to be devoted to trying to stop, regulate, or clean up after, the runs which shadow-banking assets are prone to.

There will still be an incentive to try to issue “money-like” securities at slightly higher yield, by investing in riskier securities. Such securities would still be fragile and run-prone, which is a clear market failure. Once the economy is satiated in liquidity, the need to provide liquid assets need no longer restrain regulators from insisting that any intermediary must offer investments at floating value, and thus immune to runs. Banks do not even need to be allowed to issue deposits to fund mortgages, and can be required to issue arbitrary amounts of equity or long-term debt instead.   The run-prone nature of the financial system – surely its largest cost – can easily be solved.

The emerging actual future, under Dodd-Frank, is a very highly regulated banking and shadow banking system, with a great deal of regulatory protection for incumbents. After all, too big to fail is too big to compete. The Fed is planning to reduce the interest rate on reserves, and the Treasury is not planning to issue fixed-value debt, so the shadow-banking system is likely to reemerge. This structure seems unlikely to produce much of an increase in efficiency – decline in fees and costs-- necessary to transfer an investor’s savings to a borrower’s investment. Whether it solves the “fragility” issue, especially in the era of looming sovereign debt crises, is a matter for another day.

VI. Concluding remarks

Greenwood and Scharfstein’s big picture is illuminating. The size of finance increased, at least through 2007, because fee income for refinancing, issuing, and securitizing mortgages rose; and because people moved assets to professional management; asset values increased, leading to greater fee income to those businesses. Compensation to employees in short supply – managers – increased, though compensation to others – janitors, secretaries – did not. Fee schedules themselves declined a bit.

To an economist, these facts scream “demand shifted out.” Some of the reasons for that demand shift are clearly government policy to promote the housing boom. Some of it is “government failure,” financial engineering to avoid ill-conceived regulations. Some of it – the part related to high valuation multiplied by percentage fees – is temporary.   Another part – the part related to the creation of private money-substitutes – was a social waste, has declined in the zero-interest rate era, and does not need to come back.  The latter can give us a less fragile financial system, which is arguably an order of magnitude larger social problem than its size.

The persistence of very active management, and very high fees, paid by sophisticated institutional investors, such as nonprofit endowments, sovereign wealth funds, high-wealth individuals, family offices, and many pension funds, remains a puzzle. To some extent, as I have outlined, this pattern may reflect the dynamic and multidimensional character of asset-market risk and risk premiums.  To some extent, this puzzle also goes hand in hand with the puzzle why price discovery seems to require so much active trading. It is possible that there are far too few resources devoted to price discovery and market stabilization, i.e. pools of cash held out to pounce when there are fire sales. It is possible that there are too few resources devoted to matching the risk-bearing capacities of sophisticated investors with important outside income or liability streams to the multidimensional time-varying bazaar of risks offered in today’s financial markets.

Surveying our understanding of these issues, it is clearly far too early to make pronouncements such as  “There is likely too much high-cost, active asset management,” or “society would be better off if the cost of this management could be reduced,“ with the not-so-subtle implication ( “Could be?” By whom I wonder?) that resources devoted to greater regulation (by no less naïve people with much larger agency problems and institutional constraints) will improve matters.

VII. References

Acharya, Viral V. and  Lasse H. Pedersen, 2005 “Asset pricing with liquidity risk” Journal of Financial Economics, 77, 375-410.

Adrian, Tobias, and Adam B. Ashcraft, 2012, “Shadow Banking Regulation,”  Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 559.

Alvarez, Fernando and Franceso Lippi, 2009, “Financial Innovation and the Transactions Demand for Cash,” Econometrica 77, 363–402. doi: 10.3982/ECTA7451

Ang, Andrew,  2010, “Liquidating Harvard,” Columbia CaseWorks ID#100312, http://www2.gsb.columbia.edu/faculty/aang/cases/Liquidating%20Harvard%20p1.pdf

Asness, Clifford, 2004, “An Alternative Future Part II: An Exploration of the Role of Hedge Funds.” Journal of Portfolio Management 31, 8-23.

Arrow, Kenneth J.,Robert Forsythe, Michael Gorham,Robert Hahn, Robin Hanson, John O. Ledyard, Saul Levmore, Robert Litan, Paul Milgrom, Forrest D. Nelson, George R. Neumann, Marco Ottaviani, Thomas C. Schelling, Robert J. Shiller, Vernon L. Smith, Erik Snowberg, Cass R. Sunstein, Paul C. Tetlock, Philip E. Tetlock, Hal R. Varian, Justin Wolfers, Eric Zitzewitz 2008, “The Promise of Prediction Markets,” Science 320 877-878 http://hanson.gmu.edu/promisepredmkt.pdf

Barber, Brad M.,  Yi-Tsung Lee Yu-Jane Liu, and Terrance Odean, 2008, “Just How Much Do Individual Investors Lose by Trading?” The Review of Financial Studies 22, 609-632.

Banerjee, Snehal and Ilan Kremer,  2010, “Disagreement and Learning: Dynamic Patterns of Trade,” The Journal of Finance 65, 1269–1302. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01570.x

Berk, Jonathan B. and Richard C. Green, 2004, “Mutual Fund Flows and Information in Rational Markets,” Journal of Political Economic, 112, 1269-1295.

Berk, Jonathan B., 2005. “Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management," Journal of Portfolio Management, 31, 27-31.

Berk, Jonathan and Richard Stanton, 2007, “Managerial Ability, Compensation, and the closed-end fund discount” Journal of Finance 62, 529-556.

Carhart, Mark M., 1997, “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance,” Journal of Finance 52, 57-82.

Chevalier, Judith, and  Glenn Ellison , “Risk Taking by Mutual Funds as a Response to Incentives,” Journal of Political Economy, 105, 1167-1200.

Cochrane, John H., 2003, “Stock as Money: Convenience Yield and the Tech-Stock Bubble” in William C. Hunter, George G. Kaufman and Michael Pomerleano, Eds., Asset Price Bubbles Cambridge: MIT Press 2003

Cochrane, John H., 2011, “Discount rates,” Journal of Finance 66, 1047-1108.

Cochrane, John H., 2012, “A mean-variance benchmark for intertemporal portfolio theory,” Manuscript, University of Chicago.

Cutler, David M.,  and Dan P. Ly, 2011, “The (Paper)Work of Medicine: Understanding International Medical Costs” Journal of Economic Perspectives 25, 3–25, page 8, http://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/jep.25.2.3

French, Kenneth R., 2008, “Presidential Address: The Cost of Active investing” The Journal of Finance 63(4) 1537-1573.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French 2006, “Dissecting Anomalies” Journal of Finance 63 (4) 1653-1678.

Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French, 2010, “Luck versus Skill in the Cross-Section of Mutual Fund Returns” Journal of Finance 65, 1915-1947.

Frazzini, Andrea, and Lasse Heje Pedersen, 2011a, “Betting against beta,” Manuscript, available at http://www.econ.yale.edu/~af227

Frazzini, Andrea and Lasse Heje Pedersen, 2011b, “Embedded Leverage,” Manuscript, available at  http://www.econ.yale.edu/~af227

Friedman, Milton, 1969, The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine.

Greenwood, Robin, and David S. Scharfstein, 2012,  "The Growth of Modern Finance," Manuscript, Harvard University, http://www.people.hbs.edu/dscharfstein/Growth_of_Modern_Finance.pdf

Goetzmann, William N.  and Sharon Oster, 2012, “Competition Among University Endowments,” NBER working paper 18173, http://papers.nber.org/papers/W18173

Gorton, Gary, and Andrew Metrick, 2012, Journal of Economic Literature 50, 128–150.

http:www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jel.50:1.128

Grossman, Sanford G., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1980, “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets” American Economic Review 70, 393-408

Kim, Oliver, and Robert E. Verrecchia, 1991,  “Trading Volume and Price Reactions to Public Announcements,” Journal of Accounting Research 29, 302-321.

Kyle, Albert S., 1985, “Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading,” Econometrica 53, 1315-1336.

Kirilenko, Andrei, Albert S. Kyle, Mehrdad Samadi, Tagkan Tuzun, 2011, " The Flash Crash: The Impact of High Frequency Trading on an Electronic Market" Manuscript

Lamont, Owen, 2004, “Go Down Fighting: Short Sellers vs. Firms” Manuscript, Yale University

Lucas, Robert E., Jr., 2000, “Inflation and Welfare,” Econometrica, 68, 247–274.

Lucca, David O., and Emanuel Moench 2012, “The Pre-FOMC Announcement Drift,”  Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Milgrom, Paul, and Nancy Stokey, 1982, "Information, trade and common knowledge," Journal of Economic Theory 26, 17-27.

Paul Vigna and Tom Lauricella (2012) “Sawtooth Trading Hits Coke, IBM, McDonald’s, and Apple Shares” Wall Street Journal July 19, 2012, http://blogs.wsj.com/marketbeat/2012/07/19/sawtooth-trading-hits-coke-ibm-mcdonalds-and-apple-shares/

Philippon, Thomas  2008 “The Evolution of the US Financial Industry from 1860 to 2007: Theory and Evidence,” Manuscript, New York University

Pastor,  Lubos, and Robert F. Stambaugh, 2012, “On the Size of the Active Management Industry,” Journal of Political Economy 120, 740-781

Scheinkman, Jose, and Wei Xiong, 2003, "Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles," Journal of Political Economy,  1183-1219.

Weller, Brian, 2012, "Liquidity and High Frequency Trading," Manuscript, University of Chicago Booth School of Business.



Footnotes

[1]Affiliations: University of Chicago Booth School of Business, NBER, Hoover institution and Cato Institute. John.cochrane@chicagobooth.edu; http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/. (back)

[2] This is a response essay prepared for the Journal of Economic Perspectives, following Greewnood and Sharfstein (2012) “The growth of modern finance.” (back)

[3] Sources: BEA, GDP by industry and Census, 2007 Economic Census. For advertising, http://www.wpp.com/wpp/press/press/default.htm (back)

[4]Cutler and Ly (2011) p. 8, also http://thirdcoastfestival.org/library/1223-the-battle-over-billing-codes (back)

[5] The trend continues. On January 3 2012, the Wall Street Journal reported that in 2012 investors pulled $119 billion out of actively-managed funds, capping 5 years of $50-$140 billion annual withdrawals; and put $154 billion into stock and bond exchange-traded funds. “Investors sour on pro stock pickers,” http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424127887323689604578217944033194874.html (back)

[6] “Alpha” is the risk-adjusted expected return. It is most conventionally defined by a regression of a fund’s return, in excess of the risk free rate, on a constant and a set of index excess returns or “benchmarks.” The constant is then “alpha,” and is conventionally interpreted as extra average return accruing to the manager’s talent or superior information.  The slope coefficient or “beta” represents the tendency of the fund return to move with the market portfolio; this component of risk and return can be synthesized essentially for free. The simplest calculation just uses a market-wide index on the right hand side of this regression.  When portfolio strategies deviate from simple stock picking, more detailed “benchmark” indices are used to compare a manager’s performance to that available from simple passive strategies. (back)

[7] See Fama and French (2006) for example. (back)

[8] Berk and Green’s papers are much more sophisticated than this simple example,  adding the uncertainty in fund returns, and a signal extraction problem, which gives rise to interesting information extraction problems and dynamics. A large literature has followed.  Berk and Stanton (2007) consider the closed-end fund discount. Pastor and Stambaugh (2012) consider the industry size directly, and posit industry decreasing returns to scale in alpha production along with investor learning.  Berk (2005) offers a simple exposition.  (back)

[9] Chevalier and Ellison (1997). (back)

[10] See Ang (2010). (back)

[11] http://www.hmc.harvard.edu/investment-management/hybrid_model.html (back)

[12] http://www.hmc.harvard.edu/investment-management/policy_portfolio.html (back)

[13] http://investments.uchicago.edu/assetclasses.html (back)

[14] http://annualreport.uchicago.edu/page/endowment (back)

[15] http://investments.uchicago.edu/committee.html (back)

[16] Chart: Top paid CIOs of tax-exempt institutions Pensions & Investments, November 7 2011, http://www.pionline.com/article/20111107/CHART04/111109905 (back)

Load disqus comments

0 comments